back to indexJennifer Burns: Milton Friedman, Ayn Rand, Economics, Capitalism, Freedom | Lex Fridman Podcast #457

Chapters
0:0 Introduction
0:48 Milton Friedman
15:41 The Great Depression
29:58 Schools of economic thought
41:5 Keynesian economics
48:53 Laissez-faire
56:43 Friedrich Hayek
62:1 Money and monetarism
76:46 Stagflation
81:39 Moral case for capitalism
85:35 Freedom
90:34 Ethics of competition
94:20 Win-win solutions
96:9 Corruption
98:33 Government intervention
104:53 Conservatism
111:16 Donald Trump
113:52 Inflation
118:21 DOGE
123:40 Javier Milei
128:46 Richard Nixon
136:0 Ronald Reagan
139:7 Cryptocurrency
154:23 Ayn Rand
162:1 The Fountainhead
173:41 Sex and power dynamics
189:47 Evolution of ideas in history
197:15 Postmodernism
208:16 Advice to students
216:32 Lex reflects on Volodymyr Zelenskyy interview
00:00:00.000 |
The following is a conversation with Jennifer Burns, 00:00:03.760 |
a historian of ideas, including the evolution 00:00:10.240 |
in the United States in the 20th century to today. 00:00:14.180 |
She wrote two biographies, one on Milton Friedman 00:00:18.840 |
and the other on Ayn Rand, both of which I highly recommend. 00:00:31.420 |
about my previous conversation with President Zelensky, 00:00:43.960 |
And now, dear friends, here's Jennifer Burns. 00:00:54.380 |
So if we can, we will focus on each one separately, 00:01:03.040 |
skepticism of collectivism, and the ethics of capitalism. 00:01:07.880 |
Can you talk about the big picture ideas they converge on? 00:01:14.120 |
in the biggest picture, they're both individualists, 00:01:17.640 |
and they're skeptical of collectivities and collectivism. 00:01:26.960 |
and their understanding of society kind of flows from that. 00:01:30.400 |
They also both use this focus on individualism 00:01:55.680 |
and philosophical system to justify individualism 00:02:01.760 |
and to support capitalism as a social and economic system. 00:02:09.760 |
and he'll ultimately come down to freedom as his core value, 00:02:15.760 |
And so freedom does connect back to the individual, 00:02:18.800 |
but he's not justifying capitalism for his own sake, 00:02:21.480 |
he's justifying it for its ability to underwrite freedom 00:02:25.560 |
in a social sense and also in the individual sense. 00:02:29.800 |
are there interesting differences between them? 00:02:36.560 |
the justification for capitalism, maybe other ways. 00:02:43.640 |
takes a while to come to his justification of capitalism, 00:02:54.360 |
Rationality is the defining feature of human beings. 00:03:10.040 |
their interpersonal styles are really different. 00:03:11.960 |
So Friedman has big ideas, big principles that guide him, 00:03:17.720 |
He spends most of his career doing historical research, 00:03:21.160 |
economic research, pulling data from how people 00:03:24.440 |
actually make economic decisions and live in the world 00:03:27.000 |
and using them to test and refine his theories. 00:03:29.800 |
Where Rand, to some degree, we could say she's empirical 00:03:33.080 |
in that she lives through the Russian revolution 00:03:37.360 |
But her style of thinking is really first principles, 00:03:42.040 |
an axiomatic approach, going from the basic idea 00:03:53.520 |
And then they lead in some ways to really different ways 00:03:57.560 |
of thinking about how you get things done in the world. 00:04:12.640 |
In other words, we're still moving towards a place 00:04:14.840 |
where we can really hold and express these ideals purely. 00:04:18.960 |
Friedman, although he didn't use this terminology, 00:04:25.200 |
and then I'll try to move to where I really wanna be." 00:04:29.400 |
especially when he moves from being an economist 00:04:35.520 |
And so that's a really different intellectual style. 00:04:44.240 |
I mean, she wants her friends to believe what she believes 00:04:54.080 |
Milton Friedman, he also does tend to have friends 00:04:58.480 |
yet he's always willing to debate his opponents, 00:05:03.040 |
and he's willing to do so with a smile on his face. 00:05:05.440 |
You know, he's the kind of, he's the happy warrior. 00:05:16.200 |
because she gets so angry in the face of disagreement. 00:05:26.560 |
- I just re-listened to Ayn Rand's, I think, last lecture, 00:06:03.600 |
meeting her and coming to believe in her ideas 00:06:13.520 |
and that when they came to believe in objectivism, 00:06:37.440 |
and crankier and crankier over the course of her life. 00:06:43.360 |
when she was different and a little more open, 00:06:50.880 |
- Would it be fair to say that Milton Friedman 00:06:56.080 |
where he would be able to sort of evolve over time 00:07:06.080 |
the nuances of how he thought about economics 00:07:12.040 |
Friedman believed in being able to say I was wrong, 00:07:14.880 |
and there are some things he said he was wrong about. 00:07:17.400 |
We'll delve more into monetarism and monetary policy, 00:07:29.680 |
at the end of his life where he's beginning to voice 00:07:39.040 |
He really thought it would lead to a better world 00:07:44.640 |
there's a note of doubt about how globalization unfolded 00:07:59.760 |
And of course there's a phase where he does become that way, 00:08:10.160 |
that was absolutely not something Rand could do. 00:08:13.040 |
- I think there's a thread throughout this conversation 00:08:27.160 |
about two people who kind of fought for ideas, 00:08:31.400 |
for an idea like we've mentioned, freedom for capitalism, 00:08:37.680 |
And it's so interesting to see sort of the impact 00:08:40.520 |
they both had and how their elucidation explanation 00:08:45.520 |
of those ideas reverberated throughout society 00:08:50.160 |
and how we together as a society figure out what works, 00:08:53.180 |
the degree to which they have influence on the public, 00:09:00.280 |
like the Reagan administration, Nixon, and so on, 00:09:31.240 |
So these are the two greats of playing with ideas. 00:09:35.760 |
But I think that's a thread that just runs through this. 00:09:37.920 |
- Yeah, and of kind of pushing back against that movement 00:09:44.280 |
But one difference that I really should emphasize, 00:09:49.920 |
She's a philosopher, but she's also a writer of fiction. 00:09:52.080 |
So she is working almost in a mythic register, 00:09:58.400 |
She's creating characters that people identify with 00:10:01.280 |
and people relate to experiences they've had. 00:10:05.120 |
And that's one of the reasons she hits so deep. 00:10:18.080 |
- You know, having just these incredible realizations. 00:10:28.800 |
"Ayn Rand is the reason I went to medical school." 00:10:31.600 |
You know, like a woman said this to me a few years back. 00:10:34.760 |
"It never even occurred to me that I could be a doctor 00:10:37.880 |
And I said, "I'm gonna go to medical school." 00:10:39.840 |
And so she has a really intense impact on people. 00:10:46.080 |
She thought of rationality as kind of what she was doing, 00:10:50.060 |
but she was actually doing a kind of mythopoetic, 00:10:55.800 |
Whereas Friedman, on the one hand, was much more rational. 00:11:05.560 |
And it's the framework of, you know, neoclassical economics. 00:11:09.520 |
At the same time, he does pull on mythologies, you know, 00:11:15.760 |
the frontier mythology, the individual immigrant, 00:11:20.160 |
He pulls on these, but he doesn't create them. 00:11:23.520 |
And they are, he's more kind of playing a tune 00:11:34.840 |
and then take that emotional, psychological experience 00:11:39.460 |
and fuse it to an intellectual world and a political world. 00:11:43.040 |
And that's really what makes her so powerful. 00:11:46.220 |
And so I think she comes back in to relevancy 00:11:59.800 |
and kind of self-creation and self-discovery. 00:12:03.060 |
- Nevertheless, there's still pragmatic ideas 00:12:06.540 |
that are still important today for Milton Friedman, 00:12:16.740 |
Let me try to summarize who Milton Friedman is, 00:12:21.340 |
Okay, so he is widely considered to be one of the greatest 00:12:30.540 |
He was an advocate of economic freedom, like we said, 00:12:36.940 |
He strongly advocated for free market capitalism 00:12:39.820 |
and limited government intervention in the economy. 00:12:42.420 |
Though you do give, I've listened to basically everything 00:12:51.540 |
He led the famed Chicago School of Economics, 00:12:57.020 |
and he won the Nobel Prize in Economics in 1976. 00:13:03.580 |
during the Reagan administration and other administrations. 00:13:09.900 |
highly influential, not just among economists. 00:13:13.060 |
He lived 1912 to 2006, so that means he lived 00:13:25.700 |
World War II with the post-war Reconstruction, 00:13:29.740 |
the rise and fall of the Bretton Woods monetary system, 00:13:39.180 |
sort of the tensions around communism and so on, 00:13:44.340 |
And also he has some interesting relationships 00:13:46.300 |
to China's economic transformation since the 1970s, 00:14:05.780 |
You learn fast, so let me start with the economics, 00:14:15.560 |
to become a real voice in the American conservative movement 00:14:29.940 |
in revising our understanding of the Great Depression, 00:14:36.860 |
that he and Schwartz really become founders of. 00:14:51.880 |
career-making predictions, and we can dig into that. 00:14:57.560 |
he's known for the permanent income hypothesis, 00:15:01.020 |
which he develops with a group of female collaborators 00:15:10.440 |
in what becomes the Chicago School of Economics. 00:15:17.480 |
There's an earlier generation that he learns from. 00:15:22.020 |
There's also a Chicago School of Law and Economics 00:15:28.100 |
And then there'll be kind of a third generation 00:15:34.700 |
But let me go back to these kind of four pieces 00:15:47.900 |
and he is, so he's in college, it's 1928 to 1932. 00:15:52.900 |
And he's aware of the depression and he's deciding, 00:15:57.860 |
should I study mathematics or should I study economics? 00:16:01.220 |
And he hasn't, he's had some good economics teachers, 00:16:28.460 |
And so he's gonna arrive at the University of Chicago 00:16:31.940 |
when the field is struggling to know what to do. 00:16:37.660 |
where the institutional economics of the 1920s 00:16:41.380 |
has failed to predict, which was focused on business cycles. 00:16:48.540 |
And then we have the biggest business cycle of all time 00:16:52.800 |
and they don't have a good explanation for it. 00:16:59.980 |
is the remnants of a monetary understanding of the economy. 00:17:13.020 |
They look first to the, in 1933, it's bank runs, 00:17:17.100 |
failures of maybe it's up to a third of American banks. 00:17:19.740 |
It's huge, thousands of banks are failing per week. 00:17:23.300 |
So that's the first kind of imprint he will have. 00:17:31.660 |
is that all of his professors are profoundly concerned 00:17:39.980 |
They want bank regulation and financial reform. 00:17:46.660 |
So Friedman has that imprinting and then about, 00:17:55.420 |
the ideas of John Maynard Keynes from Britain, 00:17:59.800 |
Keynes has a different explanation of the Great Depression, 00:18:01.780 |
will kind of make landfall in American economics 00:18:08.900 |
But Friedman already, it's too late for Friedman. 00:18:22.700 |
federal government participation in the economy. 00:18:34.840 |
Capitalism has revealed itself to have a profound flaw 00:18:49.220 |
And so that becomes the kind of baseline of politics 00:18:54.220 |
in the United States, the understanding of the New Deal, 00:19:04.940 |
He has a hunch that there's something else going on, 00:19:13.220 |
has gone through some sort of phase transition, 00:19:16.140 |
and it worked great maybe while we had a frontier. 00:19:19.700 |
This is a very serious argument that people are making. 00:19:24.780 |
a place where Europeans hadn't fully settled. 00:19:27.820 |
Of course, they're pushing out the native tribes. 00:19:30.980 |
But that this frontier is the engine of economic growth, 00:19:42.300 |
we're just gonna have to have a more active state. 00:19:44.820 |
So Friedman is suspicious of all these assumptions. 00:19:47.940 |
And he has this idea that it's something to do with money. 00:20:01.100 |
She's working for the National Bureau of Economic Research. 00:20:03.600 |
And they come together to do this study of money 00:20:07.260 |
And it takes them 12 years to write the book. 00:20:10.700 |
And they're releasing their ideas, and they're arguing, 00:20:13.660 |
and Friedman is writing papers, giving talks, 00:20:28.460 |
And then in '63, he and Anna Schwartz publish this book, 00:20:34.700 |
It's a reinterpretation of the history of the United States 00:20:36.980 |
through money, like the central character is money, 00:20:40.300 |
whether it's BC, greenback, or the US currency. 00:20:43.660 |
And they have a whole chapter on the Great Depression. 00:21:02.900 |
of how much money has been circulating in the US 00:21:08.340 |
they find the quantity of money available in the economy 00:21:20.340 |
and we don't have any type of bank insurance at that point. 00:21:25.280 |
So if your bank goes under, your savings are there, 00:21:30.480 |
So you've put in, they can loan up to 90% on their deposits. 00:21:34.860 |
And so, Friedman and Schwartz present this argument 00:21:38.460 |
that what really made the Great Depression so bad 00:21:55.400 |
which is a fairly new institution at that time. 00:21:57.760 |
And they say, "What did the Federal Reserve do, 00:22:01.220 |
"What did it do in the face of what they're depicting 00:22:03.380 |
"as a massive unprecedented liquidity crisis?" 00:22:19.860 |
Benjamin Strong is one of them, he's now deceased. 00:22:23.060 |
And the dominance of the New York Federal Reserve, 00:22:25.860 |
which in their telling is global, it's interconnected, 00:22:30.740 |
it's seen a lot of financial things come and go, 00:22:33.500 |
and they believe that the New York Fed had the understanding 00:23:09.580 |
it's a liquidity crisis, and that in some ways, 00:23:17.820 |
The Federal Reserve could have prevented it, and it did not. 00:23:21.260 |
And so it becomes then an institutional failure 00:23:30.120 |
And so this book comes out, it's a blockbuster. 00:23:35.700 |
who've been like, "Friedman is a crank, I don't buy it," 00:23:38.680 |
are like, "Friedman and Schwartz are onto something. 00:23:41.900 |
"Milton Friedman, Anna Schwartz are onto something." 00:23:52.760 |
because "Friedman and Schwartz" becomes the playbook 00:24:02.920 |
COVID, the Federal Reserve does all kinds of new things, 00:24:09.680 |
in "Friedman and Schwartz 2.0" that somebody writes, 00:24:13.120 |
or they're the bad guy who let the economy meltdown. 00:24:19.440 |
have obviously evolved as the system has changed, 00:24:29.960 |
and that is really going to be the place he makes his mark. 00:24:36.800 |
is "A Monetary History of the United States," 00:24:39.760 |
in part, for which Milton Friedman won the Nobel Prize. 00:24:43.440 |
You've also mentioned the influence of the Great Depression. 00:24:51.520 |
- And he was, you know, mathematical proclivities. 00:24:56.200 |
So he was kind of wanting to be a mathematician. 00:25:10.780 |
that he had this choice to be a mathematician 00:25:16.360 |
mathematician is Brown University, whichever. 00:25:24.000 |
as you've described, of mathematical economics. 00:25:40.920 |
to try to solve this puzzle of the economy melting down. 00:25:46.600 |
It's one human, it's just from just zooming in, 00:25:50.120 |
I know a single human making a decision about life. 00:26:06.120 |
And also I'm going to reject the mainstream narrative 00:26:13.600 |
when he goes to Rutgers, he thinks he'll be an actuary. 00:26:15.900 |
So Milton Friedman's family, his parents are immigrants, 00:26:22.220 |
They're pretty atypical in that they don't stay in New York, 00:26:29.400 |
and they put together a fairly middle-class life 00:26:40.840 |
but it's never as precarious as he makes it out to be. 00:26:43.220 |
He's got three older sisters, they earn a good living, 00:26:45.680 |
incidentally they all have better grades in high school 00:26:48.240 |
than he does, but he's the one that goes to college. 00:26:57.040 |
because he's then looking for other father figures, 00:27:14.660 |
He's older, and he's making a career as an economist. 00:27:21.940 |
and is studying with Frank Knight at Chicago, 00:27:30.000 |
oh, I could be an economist, that could be my career path. 00:27:33.080 |
You know, the idea to be an actuary for an insurance company, 00:27:37.800 |
but he just thought that was something he could do 00:27:45.240 |
And then I think it's really key that, again, 00:27:55.720 |
And the math part is a really interesting aspect 00:28:04.440 |
to study with the mathematical economist, Henry Schultz, 00:28:08.480 |
but he gets there, and he thinks Schultz is kind of dumb. 00:28:15.400 |
and he just thinks this guy's not that smart. 00:28:21.080 |
in the early stages of mathematical economics, 00:28:23.320 |
but a lot of the oral histories about him are like, 00:28:38.040 |
And Frank Knight is against math and economics. 00:28:41.120 |
Frank Knight is like a neoclassical economist, 00:28:47.120 |
He's really concerned about liberal democracy, 00:28:52.840 |
And Friedman is very deeply influenced by Knight, 00:28:56.320 |
and he continues to pursue mathematical economics. 00:28:58.640 |
So he'll go, for part of his graduate career, 00:29:05.640 |
and he works with a mathematical economist there. 00:29:17.220 |
but it's not really where his intellectual heart and soul are. 00:29:32.480 |
We need to work on empirical, work off empirical data, 00:29:47.200 |
is it should actually predict stuff that happens. 00:30:00.680 |
You mentioned neoclassical, we mentioned Keynesian economics, 00:30:08.800 |
- Where does Austrian economics fit into that pile, 00:30:20.640 |
and neoclassical economics, and Austrian economics? 00:30:33.320 |
Classical economics, we could think of Adam Smith 00:30:40.480 |
Classical economics does not really use math, 00:30:52.160 |
It's concerned to some degree with distribution. 00:30:58.360 |
And what tends to really define classical economics 00:31:08.680 |
So where does value come from in classical economics? 00:31:12.600 |
It comes from the labor that a person puts into it. 00:31:17.480 |
So maybe this in some ways comes from Locke's notion 00:31:21.720 |
of property, that you kind of mingle your labor 00:31:45.480 |
The sentences are long, the words are different, 00:31:49.120 |
So the real big transition from classical economics 00:31:59.480 |
And the marginal revolution is a scientific revolution 00:32:08.560 |
Like, you know, there'll be some breakthrough, 00:32:12.000 |
but like somebody else has sort of the same breakthrough 00:32:13.880 |
at the same time, totally, you know, differently. 00:32:16.280 |
So there's a version of marginalism that's continental, 00:32:23.160 |
in the French-speaking lands, and in Britain, 00:32:31.600 |
So the theory of value in marginalism is on the margin. 00:32:36.600 |
So say you have one apple and you want a second one, 00:32:42.400 |
how much is going from one apple to two apple worth for you? 00:32:49.440 |
If you had 10 apples, maybe going to 11 apples 00:32:55.800 |
So what marginalism does though, most importantly, 00:33:05.520 |
You can depict this relationship graphically. 00:33:11.760 |
in the history of economics that shows a lot of the people 00:33:14.920 |
who developed marginalism were looking to physics 00:33:19.360 |
as a model, physics, the queen of the sciences. 00:33:22.360 |
And so they were thinking, they imported terms 00:33:26.360 |
from the natural world to describe the social world 00:33:29.320 |
through the lens of economics, terms like equilibrium. 00:33:32.680 |
So the idea being that if you looked at a market, 00:33:39.160 |
when everybody has bought and sold all that they want, 00:33:43.600 |
or the price will settle at an equilibrium price 00:33:46.800 |
when it's really the demand and supply are matching up. 00:33:49.920 |
- And some of these ideas are things we would pick up 00:33:57.600 |
This is sort of the basic foundation of microeconomics, 00:34:03.200 |
And so in the German-speaking intellectual tradition, 00:34:10.320 |
And people picking up the marginal revolution 00:34:12.680 |
in the German-speaking lands are opposed to the historicists 00:34:34.000 |
Or the marginalists, remember, are inspired by physics, 00:34:37.640 |
and this is a set of natural laws that applies anywhere 00:34:55.600 |
adhere, and become expressed in certain types of societies? 00:35:17.960 |
But at that point in time, late 19th century, 00:35:25.400 |
and how fast does the ball roll from one to the other? 00:35:29.960 |
And eventually, economists will start to create 00:35:35.840 |
So we're in late 19th century and we have this fissure, 00:35:39.080 |
we have this introduction of marginal analysis 00:35:48.000 |
but we still have this fissure between historical thinking 00:36:01.600 |
this ends up mapping onto debates about capitalism. 00:36:08.560 |
tend to be interested in the progressive movement, 00:36:19.280 |
Factory safety laws, wage laws, working conditions laws. 00:36:29.520 |
all use marginal analysis just in different ways. 00:36:32.760 |
The ones who are more drawn to marginal analysis 00:36:40.240 |
the neo is because they're using marginal analysis. 00:36:45.080 |
we need to change the way the economy operates 00:36:49.800 |
Whereas the progressives are saying things like, 00:36:55.760 |
The state and the people collectively and democratically 00:37:22.320 |
And the neoclassical economists are still there, 00:37:29.520 |
is one of the minority neoclassical economists. 00:37:32.880 |
And the institutionalists are much more progressive. 00:37:38.280 |
- Is it fair to say that the neoclassical folks 00:37:56.560 |
the progressive folks, has more intervention. 00:38:08.200 |
is the first generation of progressive economists 00:38:12.760 |
They were closely allied with the socialist movement, 00:38:17.800 |
And many of them lost their jobs at universities. 00:38:43.800 |
because the 1920s are a fairly peaceful decade 00:38:47.720 |
So this is a situation when the Great Depression hits. 00:39:01.120 |
he's written a whole book on business cycles. 00:39:04.600 |
But he doesn't see this business cycle coming 00:39:07.440 |
and he doesn't have a good explanation for it. 00:39:09.160 |
Now, perhaps the preeminent neoclassical economist 00:39:12.800 |
Now Irving Fisher is big into the stock market. 00:39:16.440 |
And Irving Fisher says sometime in late summer, 1929, 00:39:35.560 |
and there's an enormous economic crisis all around. 00:39:42.000 |
- Yes, and the other thing he's stepping into 00:39:50.880 |
at the system, unemployed people on the street. 00:40:10.960 |
He calls himself an old-fashioned liberalism. 00:40:28.280 |
and this is putting too many strains on the system. 00:40:47.280 |
their unhappiness with what's happening economically. 00:40:55.640 |
Friedman is a part that becomes the very early stirrings 00:40:59.440 |
of trying to think about a new sort of liberalism, 00:41:02.840 |
which will eventually be called neoliberalism. 00:41:05.240 |
- Okay, so if we can just linger on definitions of things. 00:41:32.560 |
- So the real battle is Keynesian versus everybody else. 00:41:36.680 |
- That is what eventually comes to pass in the United States 00:41:41.840 |
in the kind of developed profession of economics. 00:41:58.200 |
People start using more statistical and mathematical tools 00:42:04.360 |
and they're given a boost sort of inadvertently 00:42:08.400 |
So Keynes is trained in the neoclassical tradition. 00:42:15.560 |
He's been there in the peace negotiations at Versailles. 00:42:21.000 |
He's like, "Hey, we're gonna have another war here 00:42:48.040 |
there's a natural mechanism to bring them back up. 00:43:07.600 |
and then you regenerate prosperity in that way. 00:43:10.080 |
And so Keynes says, "Sure, that's one theory, 00:43:14.880 |
but something different is happening right now." 00:43:18.840 |
is because the working class is more empowered now. 00:43:23.280 |
They're not simply going to just take low wages 00:43:28.440 |
But also he says people might become too anxious to spend. 00:43:37.760 |
And Keynes has these discussions of animal spirits, right? 00:43:44.240 |
to think not just in terms of human rationality, 00:43:47.240 |
but what are some other things going on in human beings? 00:43:49.520 |
And people might decide to sit on their money. 00:44:01.080 |
the equilibrium kind of restarts and resets itself. 00:44:24.240 |
kind of ramifies out throughout the economy." 00:44:26.480 |
So it takes the government and puts it in the center 00:44:30.480 |
as opposed to say the banking system or the financial system 00:44:35.280 |
And for many economists of Friedman's generation, 00:44:48.920 |
because they come in to grad school in economics 00:44:51.680 |
and they get exposed to the new ideas of John Maynard Keynes 00:44:54.600 |
and they, I think it's Paul Samuelson calls it, 00:45:04.960 |
immediately succumbed and like no one under 50 00:45:10.680 |
And so Keynesianism, Keynes himself is very suspicious 00:45:38.840 |
Franklin Roosevelt is not really a Keynesian. 00:45:42.080 |
He's kind of an accidental or experimental Keynesian. 00:45:46.280 |
And there's a bunch of different ideas in the United States 00:46:00.120 |
that you can construct models in the Keynesian perspective. 00:46:13.760 |
and you seem like you have a lot more authority. 00:46:18.040 |
And so math becomes really twinned into Keynesian economics. 00:46:23.040 |
- So numbers are used as a kind of a symbol of expertise. 00:46:36.240 |
the interest rate is here and taxes are here. 00:46:46.400 |
So the other piece of the Keynesian revolution 00:46:49.320 |
is it really gets people thinking kind of holistically 00:47:02.800 |
will end up calling the neoclassical synthesis. 00:47:06.840 |
If you take micro, you're gonna get supply and demand, 00:47:18.160 |
And so the idea is that, and this makes sense. 00:47:20.760 |
I mean, you can think of this from statistics, right? 00:47:30.360 |
where economists are using kind of neoclassical tools 00:47:39.320 |
when they think about the economy as a whole. 00:47:41.080 |
And in this paradigm of the economy as a whole, 00:47:43.920 |
the federal budget, the taxing and spending power 00:47:51.640 |
And that's really the essence of Keynesianism. 00:47:56.960 |
is that Keynesianism and Keynes are different. 00:48:02.960 |
where John Maynard Keynes comes to DC and he goes to dinner 00:48:09.520 |
he said, "Oh yeah, it was really interesting. 00:48:16.720 |
- So Keynesianism is more government intervention, 00:48:41.880 |
And the formulation of that from Milton Friedman 00:48:52.280 |
- Yes, so the Austrians and the Chicago Schools 00:49:02.600 |
individual entrepreneurship, kind of private sources. 00:49:05.280 |
The private market is what drives economic growth, 00:49:14.320 |
And because he's lived through the Great Depression, 00:49:17.320 |
he's not laissez-faire and he won't ever be laissez-faire. 00:49:40.040 |
- So yeah, laissez-faire means leave a be in France. 00:49:43.560 |
It's more often used as an insult than as an actual. 00:49:48.200 |
Very few people are completely and totally laissez-faire. 00:49:53.440 |
would be the sort of pure, maybe pure anarchist position, 00:49:56.720 |
like the state does nothing or the state isn't even there. 00:50:00.360 |
But it tends to, if I could maybe make it more precise, 00:50:13.040 |
and the seller of labor must have absolute freedom 00:50:17.560 |
So that means no minimum wage law, no working hours law, 00:50:24.640 |
That was, and this is all pre-progressive movement. 00:50:29.160 |
You know, imagine you're in 19th century America 00:50:32.960 |
and you hire someone to help you in the farm. 00:50:37.720 |
If they fall off a ladder and break their back, 00:50:40.080 |
maybe you help them out, maybe you don't, right? 00:50:41.680 |
But there's not a whole apparatus of legal liability 00:50:53.160 |
So no regulation of who can invest in a nation 00:51:01.120 |
So Nippon Steel could come and invest in U.S. Steel 00:51:04.680 |
and there would be no grounds in which to reject that. 00:51:08.040 |
Or you could, as a billionaire in the United States, 00:51:11.600 |
relocate you and all your money to another country 00:51:14.320 |
and the United States couldn't try to keep you 00:51:16.240 |
and nobody else could stop you from coming in. 00:51:18.560 |
And so, and then in the context of economic crisis, 00:51:40.320 |
and people need to be desperate enough to start taking work 00:51:46.680 |
So the theory would be if you give people relief, 00:51:51.360 |
Now, almost nobody says that in the Great Depression 00:51:57.240 |
and it's, you know, people are starving on the street 00:52:00.480 |
and people feel, for humanitarian and ethical reasons, 00:52:05.400 |
The Austrians, though, at first, Hayek and Lionel Robbins 00:52:14.560 |
And then pretty soon, Hayek has to change his tune. 00:52:21.320 |
- Absolutely, and so Hayek will make the turn 00:52:27.120 |
and then will come to talk about how the state needs 00:52:30.200 |
to support what he calls a competitive order. 00:52:36.440 |
still remains very hardcore and is not really open 00:52:46.320 |
- What does von Mises say about, like, human suffering 00:52:49.360 |
that's witnessed in the Great Depression, for example? 00:52:51.640 |
Like, what are we supposed to, as economists, 00:53:01.600 |
- Yeah, I wish I knew an answer to that question. 00:53:08.800 |
I think I would hazard that he would look more 00:53:13.800 |
down the road and say, "Well, if you start here, 00:53:20.960 |
but I don't factually know what he said in response. 00:53:25.080 |
I do know that Hayek's position doesn't last very long. 00:53:40.120 |
Most who were were kind of small-town electeds, 00:54:06.680 |
and certainly there were members of the Federal Reserve 00:54:14.160 |
but it would create what we now call moral hazard, 00:54:16.240 |
bad habits, were we to intervene and to save failing banks 00:54:19.720 |
because failing banks need to be taught a lesson. 00:54:27.720 |
This is discipline, and if you remove the discipline, 00:54:32.200 |
you'll be taking away something fundamental in society. 00:54:41.600 |
is the number of incredibly radical proposals 00:54:49.380 |
Another really important influence on Friedman 00:54:52.240 |
was Henry Simons, who was a junior professor at Chicago, 00:54:57.240 |
and Simons had this idea for what he called 100% money, 00:55:04.400 |
banks have to hold 100% of the deposits they receive. 00:55:18.440 |
and then there's gonna be a category of sort of, 00:55:30.480 |
the investment banks were split from the deposit banks, 00:55:44.400 |
Go off the gold standard, restrict the currency, 00:55:48.280 |
change the banks, immediately relief payments now. 00:55:55.360 |
is that they thought of all of those as emergency measures 00:56:06.080 |
and not permanent alterations between state and market, 00:56:09.480 |
where the Keynesian assumption is things have changed, 00:56:12.200 |
times have changed, we're in a new dispensation, 00:56:21.560 |
to doing things differently in a state of emergency. 00:56:25.300 |
He will have different ideas during World War II 00:56:32.880 |
of at least the first rounds of coronavirus relief, 00:56:39.460 |
So in that way, he was definitely more flexible. 00:56:55.040 |
- Sure, so F.A. Hayek is an Austrian economist 00:57:01.760 |
and he's a mentor, a mentee, rather, of Ludwig von Mises. 00:57:10.800 |
Austrian capital theory, and the Depression hits, 00:57:14.260 |
and he's one of the few economists who, in the beginning, 00:57:21.280 |
although as he realizes how politically unpalatable that is, 00:57:32.000 |
What's significant about Hayek is that he is also watching 00:57:35.360 |
what's happening in Austria, what's happening in Germany, 00:57:38.280 |
and he's really worried the same thing is going to happen 00:57:43.640 |
and he sees the root cause of this is socialism, 00:57:47.160 |
the shift towards an expanded role for government, 00:57:54.000 |
and so he writes this book that becomes incredibly famous, 00:57:57.160 |
"The Road to Serfdom," basically saying taking these steps 00:58:04.040 |
that's a modified form of capitalism is going to, could, 00:58:07.960 |
he's very clear that this is not an inevitability, 00:58:14.060 |
we may end up in a sort of coercive, totalitarian state. 00:58:18.160 |
So this becomes enormously popular in the United States. 00:58:22.080 |
First of all, he's in good touch with Friedman's teachers, 00:58:33.600 |
They call themselves old-fashioned, unreconstructed liberals, 00:58:39.240 |
Hayek will be trying to kind of organize thinkers 00:58:43.000 |
and intellectuals who he believes shares his values, 00:58:47.000 |
of what we would call today classical liberalism, 00:58:53.600 |
Now, Hayek also chooses not to argue against Keynes, 00:58:58.440 |
and he feels that this is a huge missed opportunity, 00:59:01.480 |
that he should have staked out the case against Keynes, 00:59:06.240 |
people come to believe there is no case against Keynes. 00:59:18.120 |
specifically developing the Mont Pelerin Society, 00:59:33.480 |
to think about what Hayek calls the competitive order, 00:59:43.680 |
That is the system of laws, of norms, of practices, 00:59:48.120 |
that makes it possible for markets to function. 00:59:53.360 |
between the older philosophy of laissez-faire, 00:59:56.880 |
and the newer reconceptualization of liberalism, 01:00:02.160 |
We need a state that's not intervening in markets 01:00:11.560 |
so that they can function with maximum freedom, 01:00:21.920 |
the type of either inequality or social instability 01:00:25.640 |
that will call the whole system into question. 01:00:37.280 |
as mathematics becomes the language of economics, 01:00:44.520 |
Now, Friedman, to some degree, is left out in the cold, 01:00:56.480 |
And he literally drives the mathematical economists 01:01:00.800 |
They're clustered in a group called the Kohl's Commission, 01:01:10.040 |
But then when Hayek arrives at the University of Chicago, 01:01:24.920 |
So he has an appreciation for Hayek as a social thinker, 01:01:33.160 |
his answer to Keynes will be deeply empirical, 01:01:38.400 |
and it will create an alternative intellectual world 01:01:52.640 |
and ideological diversity into the field of economics, 01:02:10.080 |
"Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon." 01:02:14.440 |
And it's fascinating that he becomes an expert in inflation 01:02:21.600 |
and the first major research product of monetarism 01:02:45.240 |
is related to the amount of money circulating in an economy. 01:02:58.880 |
but Friedman is saying this very basic relationship 01:03:02.080 |
holds true even in an advanced industrial economy. 01:03:06.120 |
And that is what people have started to doubt. 01:03:09.640 |
And if you think about money, you think about banks, 01:03:14.600 |
about the federal budget spending and taxation. 01:03:17.800 |
And what you see happens in American economics, 01:03:21.000 |
the textbooks previous to the Keynesian Revolution, 01:03:28.680 |
and other scholars have done the word counts. 01:03:44.560 |
It just looks away from money to other things. 01:03:49.400 |
"No, money still matters, money still counts." 01:03:53.240 |
And it's a very counterintuitive argument to make. 01:04:02.440 |
With Anna Schwartz, he develops this 150-year timeframe. 01:04:06.880 |
He also has students working on episodes of hyperinflation 01:04:20.960 |
This is something that recurs throughout time. 01:04:33.920 |
Maybe once it was relevant, but it's not relevant today. 01:04:49.440 |
And it wants to pay this debt back at a low interest rate, 01:05:03.880 |
And the Federal Reserve has been so discredited 01:05:07.840 |
that the Treasury basically runs the Federal Reserve 01:05:27.480 |
And the Federal Reserve gets its independence, 01:05:39.280 |
a regime in which the Federal Reserve has no power, 01:05:41.800 |
a regime in which there is really little inflation. 01:05:46.560 |
just a little burst of inflation in the Korean War. 01:05:49.120 |
And they're saying inflation's not really important, 01:05:52.560 |
and money's not really relevant and important. 01:05:54.960 |
And so to break through and to make the argument, 01:05:57.800 |
that's why Friedman and Schwartz go to history, 01:06:00.880 |
and they're able to make that argument for history. 01:06:08.520 |
you know, when I look at economic fluctuations, 01:06:14.480 |
in the money supply and says, look, they fit. 01:06:18.640 |
they're building complicated mathematical models, 01:06:23.880 |
And they just think it's dumb, it's not interesting, 01:06:26.880 |
it's not true, they just, they don't buy it at all. 01:06:29.960 |
And so, but after a monetary history of the United States, 01:06:37.360 |
Friedman is hammering this idea of monetarism, 01:06:39.480 |
and it starts to become something respectable, 01:06:44.360 |
bordering on respectable for other economists 01:06:52.840 |
where if you start to give Friedman any credence, 01:06:56.000 |
you're heading towards a monetarist position. 01:07:16.360 |
who brings in a lot of Harvard and Yale professors 01:07:24.800 |
that are really guided by the Keynesian philosophy. 01:07:27.560 |
And Barry Goldwater is tremendously controversial, 01:07:38.000 |
in an age when that's not in the political mainstream 01:07:41.080 |
or not discussed in the political mainstream. 01:07:43.400 |
And I mean, he's just tremendously unpopular, 01:07:53.320 |
And so that actually really affects monetarism, 01:07:55.920 |
because people feel that this is now becoming 01:08:15.920 |
there is a movement that calls itself conservatism, 01:08:18.800 |
and Friedman is very tightly allied with this movement 01:08:22.680 |
partly through his friendship with William F. Buckley. 01:08:31.640 |
we could have a whole separate podcast on this. 01:08:36.960 |
in the United States becomes a political brand 01:08:55.600 |
about Milton Friedman's advocacy of more free markets, 01:09:03.040 |
And that gets folded into American conservatism, 01:09:20.040 |
And he starts writing a column for Newsweek magazine, 01:09:24.840 |
in a much more consolidated media environment. 01:09:29.440 |
And so his public profile really starts to rise 01:09:35.760 |
as an alternative to the Keynesian synthesis. 01:10:00.840 |
contracting with each other in this beautiful way. 01:10:13.560 |
trusting the flow of money is really important. 01:10:18.960 |
And the signals that pricing and money in general provides 01:10:27.400 |
I could take some of this back again to Frank Knight. 01:10:30.120 |
So one thing Frank Knight said to all his students 01:10:33.000 |
was the market is the best allocation mechanism we have. 01:10:51.640 |
and a price sends information to buyers and sellers 01:10:56.120 |
And these are the two of the strongest arguments 01:11:01.280 |
in the price system, because it will blur information 01:11:09.880 |
And so what Friedman is really gonna add to that 01:11:13.080 |
is maybe going up a level and thinking in the macro 01:11:16.400 |
about the whole economy and how money circulates 01:11:26.440 |
is they construct what are called monetary aggregates. 01:11:36.240 |
that's believed to be circulating in people's wallets. 01:12:00.760 |
And so Schwartz and Milton Friedman start measuring 01:12:06.120 |
They focus on M1 and M2, and their favorite aggregate is M2, 01:12:11.120 |
which I believe is encompassing sort of deposits 01:12:16.220 |
The other thing to recall, there's some fine distinctions 01:12:27.760 |
And money in savings accounts can earn interest 01:12:42.520 |
And then there's different institutional architectures 01:12:50.920 |
to these aggregate amounts of money and saying, 01:12:55.440 |
these really have a lot to do with economic booms and busts. 01:12:59.960 |
When we have an expansion in the amount of available money, 01:13:06.480 |
When we have a contraction in available money, 01:13:10.720 |
And so he says, at this stage, the government, 01:13:28.320 |
or it can make money more expensive and slow things down. 01:13:38.560 |
If the government can hit the gas and then hit the brake 01:13:48.480 |
or what somebody at the Federal Reserve wants, 01:13:53.440 |
And so one of the core policy proposals of monetarism 01:13:58.280 |
is let's grow the money supply at a steady rate. 01:14:10.480 |
What matters is the steadiness in the growth rate 01:14:13.040 |
because if it's a steady growth rate, it will fade away, 01:14:22.200 |
not based on what they think is gonna happen, 01:14:33.400 |
So this is sort of the paradox of monetary policy. 01:14:43.760 |
it can just fundamentally destabilize everything. 01:14:55.560 |
and saying this is the central game of the economy. 01:14:59.120 |
Now, we live in a world where we believe this, 01:15:02.200 |
and the Federal Reserve chair can't open their mouth 01:15:11.200 |
is like a mysterious and secretive organization. 01:15:15.000 |
It's not well-known, it's not deeply appreciated. 01:15:17.880 |
Some of the only people who appreciate the Fed's power 01:15:20.640 |
are like hardcore rural populists who have constituents, 01:15:25.640 |
who think the banks and money power are the problem, 01:15:29.600 |
who are like throwbacks from the frontier days. 01:15:31.840 |
So Friedman in the beginning has no constituency 01:15:40.240 |
And so just going back to summarize monetarism, 01:15:43.360 |
it's looking, it's using the quantity theory of money 01:15:49.760 |
It's proposing a policy of slow and steady growth 01:15:55.760 |
And then it is arguing that inflationary episodes, 01:16:02.480 |
by changes in the money supply, not by anything else. 01:16:06.880 |
- I mean, and going even up a level as we started, 01:16:17.640 |
to hold this idea, and then to convince the United States 01:16:24.760 |
that today we believe is mostly correct for now? 01:16:31.760 |
- And so just this idea that goes against the experts 01:16:40.320 |
the biggest, the most powerful economy in the world. 01:16:43.880 |
- Yeah, so I mean, that's a fascinating story. 01:16:59.320 |
And he is asked in that role to give a presidential address. 01:17:02.840 |
And so he gives this presidential address, December 1967. 01:17:07.280 |
And he says, "I'm gonna talk about inflation. 01:17:16.560 |
And this is what's generally known as the Phillips Curve. 01:17:41.880 |
And so this relationship has led policymakers 01:17:51.000 |
you could let inflation kind of go a little bit. 01:17:54.880 |
And in the crude forms, it becomes to seem like a menu. 01:17:59.440 |
Like you could take your model and you could plug in, 01:18:05.120 |
And it would say, "Well, great, this is how much inflation 01:18:07.880 |
And so then you would target that inflation rate. 01:18:10.000 |
So Friedman gets up and he says, "This is wrong. 01:18:23.800 |
"Once it gets going, it tends to build on itself." 01:18:44.680 |
Then people, eventually the wages will go up too high 01:18:52.560 |
or companies will decide, "At these high wages, 01:18:56.800 |
So if inflation keeps going, eventually over the long-term, 01:19:05.840 |
"where you have high inflation and high unemployment." 01:19:09.840 |
but he says, "Theoretically, this could happen." 01:19:13.100 |
"And the government has started expanding the money supply. 01:19:16.760 |
"It started expanding the money supply in 1966. 01:19:22.720 |
"and then we're gonna get a bunch of unemployment." 01:19:25.200 |
And he estimates about how long it will take. 01:19:29.760 |
"it will take about 20 years to get back to normal." 01:19:37.920 |
- Stagflation of the 1970s. - How gangster is that 01:19:54.500 |
and most deeply dislike his politics in the 1970s 01:20:01.600 |
They start to see in the data that he's right. 01:20:04.120 |
And a very parallel process happens in Britain. 01:20:08.720 |
sort of burst of spending, burst of inflation. 01:20:10.940 |
And so Friedman is vindicated in this very profound way, 01:20:23.760 |
is really the sort of final breakthrough of his ideas 01:20:30.400 |
and to thinking about how we should intervene 01:20:42.800 |
- And I don't know if we said, but to make clear, 01:20:46.300 |
stagflation means high unemployment and high inflation, 01:20:52.960 |
was not seen before and he predicted accurately. 01:20:55.960 |
And it also disproves the sort of the relationship, 01:21:14.960 |
But Friedman's warning is still very much apt 01:21:47.060 |
- So as you mentioned, Milton Friedman searched 01:21:51.560 |
Frank Knight was a big influence on Milton Friedman 01:21:58.400 |
of understanding the moral justification of capitalism. 01:22:01.680 |
I think you spoke about Knight's case for capitalism 01:22:05.120 |
was grounded in the idea that the ability to act 01:22:11.040 |
and it should because taking risks should be rewarded. 01:22:17.000 |
in the face of uncertainty should create profit. 01:22:30.600 |
And to his mind, it comes from the entrepreneurial function 01:22:42.840 |
and why it's the most effective allocation machine 01:22:48.480 |
in a way he believes that a socialist system never could. 01:22:51.720 |
Now, Knight though, is not a booster of capitalism. 01:22:55.120 |
It could be in part because he's just a darkly pessimistic 01:22:59.440 |
And so he's afraid that capitalism is gonna collapse 01:23:03.160 |
and socialism or fascism is gonna take over or communism. 01:23:07.200 |
And so he kind of descends into darkness there. 01:23:10.560 |
Friedman as the more optimist believes with Hayek 01:23:14.720 |
that you can develop a different approach to capitalism 01:23:18.340 |
that would preserve the price system, preserve allocation 01:23:21.300 |
but build in social supports, build in a social minimum, 01:23:30.580 |
And basically the whole sort of conservative movement 01:23:33.460 |
or people who we later call the conservative movement 01:23:37.420 |
And he starts thinking about what makes capitalism work 01:23:41.580 |
is that if you put forth effort, you get a reward. 01:23:44.540 |
So then you could say, well, people get what they deserve 01:23:46.780 |
under capitalism, but then he kind of stops and he says, 01:23:50.480 |
because we're born with such different endowments 01:23:55.880 |
So some people are just in the right position 01:24:06.520 |
And he also kind of has like an ethical reaction 01:24:10.520 |
which he ends up calling like an aesthetic reaction. 01:24:12.840 |
He's kind of like, it just doesn't feel right to say that. 01:24:16.400 |
And so he struggles for a while with like, what do I say? 01:24:23.980 |
Discipline of the market can't be the core to your ethics. 01:24:32.940 |
and capitalism makes individual freedom possible 01:24:35.820 |
because capitalism is dedicated to maximizing that. 01:24:38.780 |
And so the defense of capitalism comes through freedom 01:24:47.040 |
he's able to set aside nice worry about inequality 01:24:52.380 |
and this is true for the macro data at mid-century, 01:25:00.120 |
if a country goes from say a more feudal agrarian society 01:25:04.320 |
to a more market-based society, incomes will converge. 01:25:21.040 |
is a problem that can be addressed through specific policies. 01:25:25.980 |
And it's not a fundamental feature of capitalism. 01:25:30.200 |
as an engine of inequality, the way that Frank Knight did 01:25:33.360 |
and the way that maybe some critics on the left would. 01:25:38.760 |
So individual freedom, economic freedom, political freedom, 01:25:44.980 |
the dynamic between those different freedoms for him? 01:25:47.780 |
- So he really begins focusing on economic freedom. 01:25:54.320 |
because in the United States, we don't value it enough. 01:26:04.620 |
the ability to make decisions about your business, 01:26:06.720 |
the ability to make decisions about the work that you do. 01:26:13.300 |
He believes the minimum wage has bad social effects, 01:26:15.620 |
but he also believes you should be free to accept a job 01:26:30.040 |
if you create an unsafe product, it won't sell. 01:26:32.720 |
And that will be, that's sort of your incentive. 01:26:39.780 |
and he's really speaking from his vantage point 01:26:43.460 |
to the kind of liberal consensus of the '50s and '60s, 01:26:46.460 |
he thinks economic freedom has been undervalued 01:26:52.060 |
He's really kind of taking political freedom for granted. 01:26:55.100 |
Now, later in his career, when he becomes famous, 01:26:57.140 |
he's traveling the world, he spends time in Chile. 01:27:00.740 |
And this country is now being ruled by a dictator, 01:27:04.220 |
Augusto Pinochet, who starts introducing economic freedom, 01:27:12.940 |
and tells Pinochet, you've got economic freedom, 01:27:19.620 |
Pinochet's like, okay, fine, not really interested in that. 01:27:21.720 |
I wanna know what I should do about inflation. 01:27:26.420 |
he is attacked and vilified for having been a supporter. 01:27:30.900 |
He's interpreted that he's a supporter of the regime, 01:27:35.500 |
he has talked too much about economic freedom, 01:27:37.660 |
and he hasn't talked enough about political freedom. 01:27:43.780 |
So then he starts recalibrating them and saying, 01:27:46.780 |
you know what, if you don't have political freedom, 01:27:48.820 |
you're never gonna be able to hold on to economic freedom. 01:28:01.240 |
Now, let's fast forward to the end of his life, 01:28:07.260 |
So, capitalist economies that are doing very well, 01:28:14.180 |
but then he observes they don't have political freedom 01:28:16.800 |
in that you can't vote in a free and fair election, 01:28:20.180 |
but they also don't have a Stasi, they don't have a KGB, 01:28:23.620 |
they're not hauling people off for their wrong opinions. 01:28:27.460 |
So then he says they have something called civic freedom, 01:28:35.980 |
interpersonal relations, but you can't be political. 01:28:44.100 |
I think what it shows is that during the Cold War, 01:28:47.140 |
he very much believed economic and political freedom, 01:28:54.340 |
the United States, capitalism, this all went together. 01:29:00.700 |
that are using market trading and allocation, 01:29:07.540 |
Now, he always believes that China will democratize, 01:29:11.020 |
and he thinks China's on the path to democratization, 01:29:22.900 |
And he thinks that's exactly what's happening in China, 01:29:24.920 |
he sees Tiananmen, and he doesn't live long enough 01:29:29.660 |
in which doesn't look like political or civic freedom 01:29:34.940 |
- And he did oppose the dual-track system of China, 01:29:49.220 |
- He thought eventually the market would triumph. 01:29:51.640 |
- Well, that's a really powerful idea to say, 01:29:58.220 |
and eventually that's going to give political freedom. 01:30:06.580 |
and the political freedom piece will take care of itself? 01:30:09.220 |
- That's what he believed, that's what he believed. 01:30:11.340 |
Yeah, I think it's more complicated than that, right? 01:30:14.620 |
The people who gain out of a system of economic freedom 01:30:24.580 |
So, but that was, again, that's that core idea of freedom, 01:30:28.540 |
right, and that core belief that people want freedom, 01:30:34.700 |
- Just to go back to Frank Knight a little bit, 01:30:36.740 |
he wrote an essay called "The Ethics of Competition." 01:30:39.620 |
He had the metaphor that economic life is a game, 01:30:42.220 |
and then maybe that extends to society as a whole, 01:30:44.380 |
like the entirety of it is a competitive game. 01:30:47.220 |
And Milton Friedman, I think, adapted some of this, 01:30:55.260 |
- Yeah, I think what the metaphor of the game does 01:30:57.980 |
is it asks you, okay, well, what are the rules then? 01:31:01.580 |
And let's focus on the rules that keep the game going. 01:31:05.580 |
So he didn't use the concept of an infinite game, 01:31:17.740 |
shift from the allocation question, who's getting what? 01:31:31.460 |
And so for a while that led to the discussion of monopoly. 01:31:55.260 |
And so again, what keeps the economic game going 01:32:04.500 |
Nobody's guessing, nobody's changing the rules 01:32:11.140 |
We all know it's there, it's clear, it's easy. 01:32:20.660 |
and then it goes into the monetary growth rule. 01:32:26.820 |
monetary policy makes use of monetary policy rules. 01:32:33.300 |
but rules are used as a heuristic or a check, 01:32:43.500 |
and it was always counterposed to discretion, 01:32:47.180 |
which Friedman worried would be subject to capture 01:32:53.820 |
or if you had discretion in these very big areas. 01:33:03.780 |
to getting control of the rules or the rule makers. 01:33:18.740 |
the equilibrium that it arrives at might be different, right? 01:33:28.340 |
to go back to the idea of separating new liberalism 01:33:34.380 |
was more of a focus on what are the rules that are needed? 01:33:37.260 |
What is the competitive order that we wanna set out? 01:33:51.160 |
that becomes really important in the post '70s era 01:34:40.740 |
So being able to find rules where everybody wins, 01:34:56.060 |
which is it's not just, are people getting more? 01:35:03.600 |
And do people feel they're getting what's fair and equal? 01:35:11.940 |
if you look at the history of, going back to Chile, 01:35:22.060 |
and a high level of discontent within the society, 01:35:31.540 |
How people feel about it, how people perceive it matters. 01:35:35.420 |
And you can't, you know, we saw this recently, 01:35:37.940 |
you can't just come out with a bunch of statistics 01:35:47.920 |
and all the comparative factors that people have 01:36:01.060 |
to rising and falling, to where we sit vis-a-vis others. 01:36:04.300 |
And so that absolutely has to be attended to. 01:36:12.780 |
of the economy is different than the reality of the economy. 01:36:23.400 |
is really important in a lot of these nations. 01:36:34.840 |
The reality of corruption can be way different 01:36:48.540 |
- Yeah, I mean, this goes back to Keynes' analysis 01:36:59.980 |
And in some ways, this simple analysis of the problem 01:37:03.860 |
and proposal of a solution was enough to restore 01:37:08.060 |
eventually the path to academic prosperity, right? 01:37:14.660 |
You know, the sense of we know we have a future, 01:37:18.920 |
And to go back to thinking about money, right? 01:37:26.580 |
and it's a form of belief and faith in our society 01:37:37.220 |
and thought about how to control the psychology 01:37:42.680 |
- No, I mean, what's interesting is he does talk, 01:37:47.660 |
he says we have fiat currency, and this is an experiment, 01:37:52.500 |
you know, and we don't know how it's going to turn out. 01:38:20.140 |
I see that monetary systems have always, say, 01:38:30.580 |
by what I've actually seen happen in history. 01:38:36.680 |
between how much government intervention is okay 01:38:45.700 |
Can you explain, actually, the difference between the two? 01:38:58.700 |
And he basically sees this as part of the effort 01:39:04.220 |
And he basically says we have advanced societies, 01:39:09.500 |
we have decided, in keeping with our morals and our ethics, 01:39:16.780 |
The question is how are we gonna make that happen? 01:39:19.500 |
And he ended up believing the best thing to do 01:39:24.920 |
And he said you can get that based on your income. 01:39:28.740 |
If you have a lot of income, you don't get it. 01:39:37.940 |
you should base that on what was required to buy food, right? 01:39:43.140 |
You could objectively determine the nutrition 01:39:52.040 |
because it's not intervening in the price system. 01:40:02.780 |
It does not, in his view, require that you qualify for it 01:40:09.500 |
You just get it as kind of part of your membership 01:40:15.540 |
And so that to him was really different than a minimum wage 01:40:20.500 |
because it did not interfere with the work bargain. 01:40:24.960 |
His belief about minimum wages was specifically 01:40:32.860 |
was a willingness to work for a very low wage. 01:40:38.660 |
businesses, instead of hiring that higher-priced labor, 01:40:45.740 |
They put in an electronic checkout, you know, 01:40:58.540 |
And there seems to be a level at which you can set them 01:41:06.240 |
with more spending money that then powers the economy. 01:41:08.540 |
So he had a very sort of clinical analysis of that 01:41:12.880 |
rather than an empirical one or a really abstract analysis. 01:41:22.240 |
But what it is, is it's purely individualistic. 01:41:31.080 |
because American social policy typically identifies, 01:41:38.600 |
So the classic example is soldiers, veterans. 01:41:41.480 |
Another example is mothers raising dependent children. 01:41:49.320 |
And so Friedman's proposal, it really caught on in the '60s. 01:41:52.400 |
It ultimately went nowhere, but it was no litmus test, 01:41:55.480 |
no income analysis, just we're gonna give you this much. 01:42:02.440 |
And he decided once mass taxation had come in, 01:42:04.920 |
you could do it through taxes and you could just rebate. 01:42:07.640 |
People who didn't pay income taxes got a rebate. 01:42:13.520 |
And it's considered extremely successful by policy analysts. 01:42:20.280 |
And so I see that as a kind of paradigm of his thinking 01:42:30.520 |
or instead of trying to intervene in the market for labor 01:42:34.480 |
or the market for something else, the market for housing, 01:42:37.600 |
you provide a cash grant that people spend for themselves. 01:42:51.400 |
And there's a lot of discussion still about UBIs 01:42:56.380 |
And I think it's always gonna be hard to pull off 01:43:07.600 |
'cause they believe there's like a moral component here. 01:43:10.760 |
And Friedman advanced a policy that was really abstract 01:43:15.340 |
and really just kind of, it was devoid of judgment. 01:43:23.080 |
- And it really focused on not interfering with the market 01:43:34.760 |
but how does this not interfere with the market, right? 01:43:38.800 |
won't that change their incentives to work, et cetera? 01:43:41.960 |
I mean, there's a big body of research on this. 01:43:47.720 |
it's way better than the current benefits cliff 01:43:50.640 |
where you have to not work to get your benefits. 01:43:57.600 |
seems to be much lower than would be expected. 01:44:00.040 |
But I'll let the economist in the social science 01:44:04.520 |
to fight that one out and figure it out empirically. 01:44:09.440 |
It's interesting, even just how you conduct studies 01:44:11.880 |
like this, how you do these kinds of experiments, 01:44:17.760 |
'Cause a lot of the studies I saw is they're pretty small. 01:44:28.400 |
how to run economies from such small studies? 01:44:53.360 |
- You call Milton Friedman the last great conservative, 01:44:57.120 |
maybe to be a little bit sort of controversial 01:45:02.080 |
and make bold statements that get everybody excited. 01:45:11.320 |
in terms of kind of American political identities 01:45:14.520 |
and particularly the 20th century conservative movement, 01:45:18.280 |
which people are always saying this isn't conservatism. 01:45:26.280 |
Conservatism in America builds in a big component 01:45:29.600 |
of what we could call libertarianism, pro-capitalism, 01:45:37.240 |
but conservatism is about conserving institutions 01:45:40.800 |
and practices, and it has a role for the state 01:45:48.480 |
also this anti-statist, let's let the market rip. 01:46:04.880 |
but Friedman and the importance of his books, 01:46:15.720 |
of this American conservative synthesis as it evolved. 01:46:35.880 |
it's getting pushback on both the left and the right. 01:46:42.640 |
that both parties have turned away from this vision. 01:46:47.720 |
but the way that Friedman brought these pieces together, 01:46:57.840 |
in which I think of him also as a conservative, 01:47:19.520 |
You can still pick up a Friedman book and read it. 01:47:22.320 |
Where's lots of economics articles and outputs, 01:47:31.840 |
and intellectually the traditions of the field. 01:47:35.040 |
The work that he and particularly Anna Schwartz did 01:47:43.440 |
that was like completely unfashionable in his time. 01:47:52.080 |
So I think of him kind of intellectually as a conservative, 01:47:58.160 |
And so, I mean, what makes a great conservative 01:48:11.400 |
that the times when he was sort of out in public, 01:48:26.960 |
deep debate over ideas where it seems less deep now. 01:48:38.840 |
especially like for the students I teach today 01:48:41.320 |
to be like, you know, there were arguments about ideas 01:48:44.200 |
and conservatives won a bunch of them, you know? 01:48:46.640 |
And that happened in the '70s, late 1960s to 1970s, 01:48:55.360 |
this idea of stimulating the economy by spending more, 01:49:00.680 |
And the downside's called too much regulation. 01:49:05.320 |
And, you know, you've gone too far in kind of bottling up 01:49:09.360 |
the actual sources of economic growth and dynamism, 01:49:17.480 |
You know, the Great Society had all these ways of, 01:49:25.880 |
In some ways, you've actually created engines 01:49:34.160 |
You've created all these perverse incentives. 01:49:57.840 |
Right now, it seems like the ideas come after the, 01:50:03.640 |
and try to put together the underpinning of it, 01:50:09.880 |
It does seem like we lead with emotional turmoil. 01:50:13.800 |
And the ideas follow versus lead with the ideas 01:50:16.760 |
and the sort of the emotion of the masses respond. 01:50:20.920 |
So, if we think of the evolution of conservatism, 01:50:22.920 |
it was a whole set of ideas that was crafted, refined. 01:50:30.280 |
sort of really found their emotional standard bearer, 01:50:37.440 |
who incidentally had been following these ideas 01:50:39.840 |
as they developed and had been honing his ability 01:50:46.640 |
If we look at Trump as the political definer of the era, 01:51:00.600 |
So, it's interesting to watch, to see that difference, 01:51:08.600 |
with the immediacy of the media environment we're in, 01:51:18.680 |
about Donald Trump, about him winning in 2024, 01:51:29.800 |
I think that's, you know, it goes without saying. 01:51:36.840 |
He would be very alarmed by the idea of tariffs 01:51:40.480 |
and very alarmed by the return to protectionism. 01:51:43.720 |
I mean, I think he believed that part of what 01:51:49.400 |
of the 20th century, as opposed to during World War II, 01:51:53.520 |
was the world was knit together more by trade, 01:51:57.840 |
that if people traded with each other, they wouldn't fight. 01:52:05.840 |
You know, he would absolutely oppose this idea 01:52:22.840 |
I think he would find it harder to embrace Trump 01:52:35.080 |
"Okay, we have a chance to reduce the size of government." 01:52:46.120 |
and that was his concern, was not so much with debt, 01:52:49.600 |
but with the feeling that there's no mechanism 01:53:09.840 |
about the potential threats to the U.S. currency's position 01:53:49.760 |
the kind of macro insights that I think are important. 01:54:11.720 |
and saying, so today we have been living in a world 01:54:16.480 |
where people have been focused on monetary policy, 01:54:21.480 |
steady monetary policy, free trade, reducing regulation. 01:54:35.480 |
So we have Milton Friedman predict inflation in 1967. 01:54:43.560 |
and every institution was designed around stable prices, 01:54:48.560 |
and once inflation broke out, prices were no longer stable. 01:54:53.680 |
So for example, tax rates weren't inflation-adjusted. 01:54:58.160 |
So if your income went up because of inflation, 01:55:06.800 |
On paper, you have more money, but everything costs more, 01:55:14.520 |
There's a whole shift of American corporations 01:55:20.240 |
because the tax breaks they used to get for depreciation, 01:55:24.520 |
for building new factories, are not inflation-adjusted, 01:55:27.120 |
so they no longer pay off in an inflationary environment, 01:55:30.400 |
and then when Paul Volcker comes in in 1980s, early 1980s, 01:55:38.000 |
really pushes up interest rates to bring down inflation, 01:55:41.200 |
and that completely reorders the banking sector 01:55:49.960 |
and once general market interest rates exceeded that, 01:56:03.760 |
and then everyone turned against all the formulations we had 01:56:08.760 |
and said, well, these have hollowed out our industrial base. 01:56:25.200 |
and the net result of that turning away, I argued, 01:56:38.840 |
to worry about inflation, we can spend what we want, 01:56:44.480 |
and so my argument is that has now opened the door 01:56:50.240 |
which is potentially a deeply transformative moment 01:56:55.040 |
that will change the size and shape of government, 01:56:58.840 |
that may change our foreign policy profoundly, 01:57:05.000 |
it may change the demographics of our country, 01:57:22.320 |
and to profoundly underestimate how much inflation 01:57:32.640 |
this is why I think you should study history, 01:57:40.440 |
just like the banks forgot that interest rates 01:57:48.920 |
so I really do believe what history teaches you to do 01:57:52.480 |
is just have a much vaster scope in your vision, 01:57:59.560 |
of so many things happening that are different 01:58:02.840 |
and so I just hope we don't forget about inflation entirely, 01:58:07.560 |
there's quite a strong chance that Trump's policies 01:58:17.280 |
so the ironies of inflation could be continuing. 01:58:20.040 |
- Like you said, Milton Friedman would be a big fan of Doge, 01:58:41.040 |
I talk about this, is taking the price mechanism 01:59:03.560 |
I actually think that national parks are good, 01:59:05.360 |
so I hope the Doge people don't take this up, 01:59:07.400 |
but rather than an allocation to fund the national parks, 01:59:11.680 |
they should be funded by the revenue that they bring in 01:59:20.520 |
so I think that would be one of the key pieces. 01:59:23.560 |
The other thing I think he'd really be thinking about, 01:59:27.200 |
about occupational licensure and barriers to entry, 01:59:35.000 |
and sometimes it's private entities that do this, 01:59:41.440 |
so he talked about this in the case of the medical profession 01:59:46.680 |
because I think we all have a collective investment 02:00:24.680 |
and let competition through prices guide outcomes. 02:00:41.560 |
to cutting a lot of the bureaucracy of government. 02:00:46.560 |
- I think the other thing he would probably be arguing for 02:00:49.880 |
is again, go back to the design of the minimum income 02:00:59.360 |
The government's already collecting this data, 02:01:03.120 |
and they can just send the money out through the system, 02:01:17.760 |
and his analysis of that was who that really benefited 02:01:21.520 |
was the bureaucracy that processed that paper, 02:01:31.520 |
you could get help out where it was needed much quicker 02:01:39.840 |
So I think trying to cut administrative overhead 02:01:41.680 |
and what he didn't have then, which we have now, 02:01:46.440 |
and the ability to send benefits out via smartphone 02:01:53.600 |
and to handle information on a mass scale so much faster. 02:01:58.120 |
- It's painful, but I think one of the big things 02:02:00.320 |
you can do is just that, which is digitalize, 02:02:08.480 |
to where the speed of signal can be instantaneous. 02:02:13.480 |
So there's no paperwork, it goes immediately. 02:02:28.160 |
Government IT systems could be vastly improved upon. 02:02:37.220 |
And I think somebody submitted a question for me 02:02:46.820 |
What are your thoughts about government employees, 02:02:49.260 |
which there's a lot of, that are going to be hurt by Doge? 02:02:56.400 |
- And it's always a really difficult question. 02:02:59.440 |
A lot of people get fired to make room for a new system. 02:03:09.240 |
I think that's also part of why Friedman favored 02:03:15.120 |
He talked about it being sort of counter-cyclical. 02:03:21.620 |
the spending level on it would naturally go up. 02:03:23.820 |
This is what economists today call an automatic stabilizer. 02:03:26.820 |
And then when it's not needed, the cost of it goes down. 02:03:34.900 |
sweeten it with honey and have people take buyouts 02:03:37.740 |
That would certainly be a way better way to go. 02:03:48.000 |
So what do you think Milton Friedman would say 02:03:54.320 |
and what Javier Millay is trying to do in Argentina? 02:04:03.560 |
but I think he definitely appreciates Friedman. 02:04:05.520 |
And on the macro level, Friedman always understood 02:04:12.760 |
But the more you put it off, the harder it is. 02:04:19.360 |
as he's doing, to just message that short-term pain, 02:04:30.880 |
these abstract ideas and putting his policies 02:04:37.840 |
I don't know how politically persuasive it is overall. 02:04:44.320 |
He doesn't have the same sort of gifts of salesmanship 02:04:55.080 |
- Yeah, he is more chainsaw-less, like warm blanket. 02:04:59.640 |
Javier recollects this line from Milton Friedman. 02:05:10.760 |
But if you strive for freedom, you often get both. 02:05:15.680 |
- You know, I think on the big picture, definitely. 02:05:18.800 |
I mean, we've seen focusing too much on equality. 02:05:23.800 |
It can be, because equality is such an alluring word, 02:05:28.600 |
it can lead you to downgrade all kinds of other things 02:05:35.640 |
I mean, the statement is too big and too broad, right? 02:05:39.440 |
So, you know, if you're talking about freedom, 02:05:44.440 |
if by freedom you mean not having to pay taxes 02:05:51.640 |
I think that can have all kinds of knock-on effects, right? 02:06:13.600 |
sometimes they value that more than they value freedom. 02:06:22.080 |
And it's just, it's hard to make such global statements 02:06:27.680 |
But again, Malay is coming from a very different context, 02:06:31.880 |
a very different country that has seen so much upheaval, 02:06:35.720 |
so much government intervention, so much inflation, 02:06:46.680 |
there probably still is a real threat of hyperinflation. 02:06:49.880 |
There seems to be a very high level of corruption 02:06:57.040 |
So Javier Malay likes to recollect this great line 02:07:02.760 |
that if you strive for equality over freedom, 02:07:06.800 |
But if you strive for freedom, you often get both. 02:07:36.560 |
what is the freedom you're talking about, right? 02:07:38.400 |
If you're talking about the freedom of ordinary people 02:07:48.920 |
I think that can increase the equality overall. 02:07:58.200 |
or has to be, I mean, lower taxes in general, great. 02:08:01.920 |
But if you're one of the top generators of wealth, 02:08:18.960 |
and provide for those institutions that structure society, 02:08:25.160 |
So I think it's just a really broad statement. 02:08:28.920 |
But again, Malay is coming from a really different context. 02:08:35.040 |
from such upheaval, such economic devastation 02:08:46.480 |
- If we can pivot a little bit, we've talked about Reagan. 02:08:51.480 |
about how Milton Friedman navigated the Reagan 02:09:00.560 |
- Well, the Nixon administration is an interesting case 02:09:03.240 |
because, so I've been talking about inflation 02:09:09.440 |
One consequence it had is that it began to undermine 02:09:14.080 |
that was established in the wake of World War II. 02:09:19.440 |
it ended up inadvertently putting the U.S. dollar 02:09:42.600 |
and they could trade the dollars that they held for gold 02:09:47.600 |
'cause the U.S. was on a sort of modified gold standard. 02:09:54.880 |
And so the system was set up and very quickly, 02:09:59.160 |
most countries were, the dollar was at the heart of it 02:10:03.200 |
in that the converting into and out of dollars 02:10:11.560 |
what we should have is floating exchange rates. 02:10:19.400 |
a top-down design of policy, an administered policy, 02:10:42.080 |
So you have more and more dollars being printed. 02:10:49.080 |
If European nations keep trading their currency for dollars, 02:11:02.320 |
And they have the right to go to the treasury, 02:11:13.360 |
and the United States starts running out of gold. 02:11:16.960 |
They're aware this is happening through the '60s, 02:11:35.080 |
He says something like, this is a running sore 02:11:50.880 |
Nixon loved people to think he was influenced by 02:11:59.560 |
He just wanted the political benefit that came from it. 02:12:22.080 |
It's called slamming the gold window shut, done. 02:12:35.160 |
which is an unconscious echo of the Soviet new economic plan. 02:12:48.680 |
Let's go all the way to floating exchange rates. 02:12:51.160 |
And this idea was heresy within the Treasury Department. 02:12:54.680 |
Everyone's very committed to the idea of the gold standard, 02:13:01.400 |
the United States at the core of the financial system, 02:13:06.360 |
Friedman has a very close relationship with George Shultz. 02:13:17.440 |
And so Friedman is feeding Shultz all his ideas 02:13:22.040 |
about how we should move to floating exchange rates, 02:13:24.800 |
how we shouldn't try to reconstruct Bretton Woods. 02:13:29.280 |
it's funny 'cause I've read some of their accounts 02:13:34.480 |
And he can kind of sense that Friedman is in here somewhere, 02:13:46.600 |
Friedman exerts this behind the scenes influence. 02:14:01.080 |
For a while, it was like a regime of steady prices. 02:14:06.040 |
And then they call it a steady regime of changing prices 02:14:12.560 |
So that's a real measure of Friedman's influence. 02:14:15.720 |
If there had been another economist in Shultz's ear 02:14:26.080 |
And so that becomes one of these pieces of globalization. 02:14:33.600 |
in addition to these floating set capital ratios, 02:14:36.240 |
you couldn't bring capital in and out of different countries 02:14:52.440 |
I mean, he sees that Nixon is not an honest person. 02:14:57.560 |
And Nixon's dream is to create a new centrist majority. 02:15:05.080 |
on his supposed economic principles and ideals. 02:15:11.720 |
He's in communication with his old mentor, Arthur Burns, 02:15:16.840 |
And Burns is basically doing everything wrong 02:15:21.280 |
And I described this in the book in some detail, 02:15:28.800 |
Burns doesn't have a solid theory of inflation. 02:15:34.080 |
it's almost like Burns is willfully ignoring Friedman 02:15:36.840 |
and kind of doing the opposite of what Friedman says. 02:15:39.000 |
So Burns is running a very loose monetary policy. 02:15:42.280 |
Inflation is quite considerable over the '70s. 02:15:44.440 |
I mean, we were all spooked by what did it get to 6%, 02:15:47.160 |
something like that, recently for a very short time. 02:15:50.320 |
This is inflation going over 10%, hovering in 8% 02:15:55.960 |
going up and down with extremely elevated rates. 02:16:04.200 |
but the failure to tame inflation is part of it. 02:16:08.080 |
And now Reagan loves Friedman and Friedman loves Reagan, 02:16:14.680 |
like an advisory economic board, Friedman's on it. 02:16:17.360 |
He's retired now, he's entering his kind of golden years, 02:16:30.760 |
It's a monetary phenomenon that has been caused 02:16:38.600 |
The only way to end inflation is by really showing 02:16:43.480 |
and signaling that government policy has changed. 02:16:49.000 |
for a short amount of time, people will suffer, 02:16:55.840 |
And this is what you need for economic prosperity. 02:16:58.560 |
So the man who implements this policy, Paul Volcker, 02:17:15.960 |
which Friedman has said, right, money matters, 02:17:20.640 |
Pretty quickly, Volcker finds that because of inflation 02:17:25.160 |
and the financial deregulation in response to it, 02:17:27.960 |
the aggregates don't work the way Friedman said they would. 02:17:31.360 |
And so the specific policy Friedman recommends, 02:17:35.000 |
Volcker tries it for a year or so, doesn't work super well. 02:17:38.240 |
But what does work is letting interest rates go high, 02:17:44.560 |
both the general citizenry and the financial markets 02:17:47.840 |
believe like, oh, they're actually serious about inflation. 02:17:54.880 |
going forward, we're gonna whip inflation now, 02:18:00.040 |
This is why people focus so much on credibility today, 02:18:02.680 |
'cause once it's lost, it's really hard to get it back. 02:18:05.360 |
And one way Volcker gets it back is interest rates over 20%, 02:18:16.960 |
Milton Friedman is whispering in Reagan's ear, 02:18:23.600 |
Now, interestingly, he hates Volcker, Volcker hates him, 02:18:27.520 |
and Friedman will never give Volcker credit for this policy, 02:18:30.080 |
but he will give Reagan credit for this policy. 02:18:32.600 |
But he owes credit himself for keeping Reagan 02:18:37.600 |
from wobbling on this policy and just pushing it through. 02:18:43.920 |
you better do this now, you've got a four-year term, 02:19:17.680 |
and what role crypto might play in the economy? 02:19:23.680 |
Whether he would be for this idea, against this idea, 02:19:37.240 |
where people say, oh, Friedman predicted cryptocurrencies 02:19:49.000 |
he knew these would come together in some way. 02:19:51.320 |
I think he probably would see a use case for crypto. 02:19:56.320 |
He definitely would not buy the stronger forms, 02:20:02.440 |
in which we could be heading towards a future 02:20:05.320 |
in which there's many different currencies that compete 02:20:07.360 |
or that are distributed or there's a stateless currency. 02:20:17.200 |
Hayek argues for this kind of competing currency model 02:20:22.800 |
He's responding to people writing about free banking. 02:20:27.240 |
even if you developed a variety of competing currencies, 02:20:33.840 |
And that's because people just want one currency 02:20:36.360 |
that they know, they don't want a bunch of different options. 02:20:39.200 |
Even in places where there have been options to do that, 02:20:43.640 |
And then he says, secondly, the state always steps in. 02:20:46.920 |
He says, technically, theoretically, it doesn't have to. 02:20:51.600 |
I could tell you about how it could work without the state, 02:21:03.600 |
because it has so many knock-on effects to so many people. 02:21:09.640 |
find a use case for crypto, think it's interesting, 02:21:16.240 |
and we're going to have a variety of distributed currencies. 02:21:31.520 |
where the state is not controlling the money well, 02:21:34.680 |
that's when people are more turning to crypto, 02:21:36.400 |
but he says, because money is so fundamental, 02:21:39.040 |
there are going to be so much political pressure 02:21:42.280 |
on any country that gets the currency profoundly wrong 02:21:50.400 |
So, if you look at episodes of hyperinflation, 02:22:06.840 |
there's these folks like Jacob Viner, Frank Knight, 02:22:10.680 |
Henry Simons, all of these influenced the thinking 02:22:15.420 |
There's this Room 7 situation at the University of Chicago. 02:22:27.160 |
sort of like deliberate, argue in that space, 02:22:52.320 |
they become what I call them the Room 7 gang. 02:22:54.760 |
So, Room 7 is they find an old storeroom in the basement, 02:22:59.200 |
and that's where they have their jam sessions. 02:23:01.320 |
And what made this world come together was Frank Knight. 02:23:10.440 |
That, I think, was a key piece of the ingredient. 02:23:12.760 |
And then there was a sense that they were onto something 02:23:27.440 |
and then there was a parallel education piece 02:23:29.760 |
rooted in admiration for a thinker, a shared admiration. 02:23:43.360 |
and he'd written the prices of different ones 02:23:46.000 |
So, he had, you know, John Stuart Mill on liberty, 02:23:55.240 |
alongside this very formal economics curriculum. 02:24:03.080 |
and developing like a shared sense of mission. 02:24:54.120 |
And so, he immersed himself in this whole other world 02:25:19.040 |
And he really, he only had a handful of friends 02:25:25.920 |
So, he just lived and breathed ideas all day long. 02:25:31.560 |
Like, what do we know about the jam sessions? 02:25:37.480 |
Are they reading papers and discussing papers? 02:25:44.640 |
And in this case, there's several people who say 02:26:07.680 |
and then the students would kind of clutch at them. 02:26:12.840 |
And then Frank Knight fell into this terrible depression, 02:26:15.920 |
and to cheer him up, they planned a big party. 02:26:19.480 |
And they went back through all of his previous writings, 02:26:23.000 |
and they assembled them into a book that was published. 02:26:41.120 |
and then all of a sudden it all fit together in a whole. 02:26:45.640 |
what they were doing was getting inside the mind 02:26:49.600 |
and understanding the ways it all fit together, 02:26:52.160 |
and then kind of testing their ideas against Knight's. 02:26:55.760 |
And what's fascinating is one of the first papers 02:27:04.600 |
He publishes a rebuttal of Frank Knight's ideas 02:27:09.200 |
And Frank Knight, he kind of took a black swan argument. 02:27:22.240 |
And Friedman publishes this statistical paper, 02:27:24.400 |
and he says, "I can put uncertainty on a graph." 02:27:27.960 |
And so, there's that sort of Freudian killing 02:27:35.240 |
turn his back on Knight's approach and Knight's pessimism, 02:27:38.560 |
even while it's like a foundation of his thinking. 02:27:43.920 |
Is there something you could say about the thinking process 02:27:52.680 |
You mentioned there's a strong collaborative component, 02:28:03.160 |
about the argument number system that you mentioned. 02:28:06.160 |
Which I, by the way, if you're gonna explain that 02:28:08.440 |
as the tangent of a tangent, that's really awesome. 02:28:11.400 |
I think it's like number one if the other person is right. 02:28:14.880 |
- Number two means you were right and I was wrong. 02:28:22.880 |
to be quick and efficient, but in other ways, 02:28:30.360 |
First is, if you use a number, it reminds the listener 02:28:35.360 |
that it's really hard to say the words, "I was wrong." 02:28:57.040 |
And so, it's supposed to be an easy way to disagree 02:29:07.640 |
- And that's really, I mean, that's so powerful. 02:29:10.800 |
I think so much of the friction of human interaction 02:29:15.100 |
could be boiled down to just not being able to admit 02:29:23.560 |
And to be able to do that, that's really powerful. 02:29:32.960 |
but can we just generalize to how he engaged in collaboration, 02:29:41.880 |
- So, he taught at the University of Chicago, 02:29:46.960 |
And he spent the summers in New Hampshire or Vermont. 02:29:56.000 |
And so, when he's at Chicago, he's teaching, he's arguing. 02:30:00.440 |
Some people loved his teaching style, very much in charge, 02:30:05.200 |
very much keeping students on their toes, confrontational. 02:30:15.000 |
And so, I think it was kind of go time when he was teaching. 02:30:27.600 |
Then he would go and do these very deep dives 02:30:31.560 |
He would also regularly do these trips to New York 02:30:34.520 |
to see Anna Schwartz, so his 12-year collaborator. 02:30:37.240 |
They didn't have, phone calls were really expensive. 02:30:39.440 |
They did have quite an extensive correspondence, 02:30:46.800 |
going to Raleigh, stop in New York, see Schwartz, 02:30:51.760 |
So, you'd have these deep check-ins at that point. 02:30:55.120 |
is people would come visit him in New Hampshire. 02:31:15.400 |
and then they would argue and talk into the night. 02:31:18.040 |
So, I think he did need that deep focus time, 02:31:23.760 |
he also lived a very engaged, very embedded social life. 02:31:37.320 |
It was vibrant, and they wrote a biography together? 02:31:51.440 |
And he was extremely extroverted, optimistic, high energy. 02:31:56.440 |
And they also were at a time when it was really clear, 02:32:00.400 |
like, for broader society, these are the roles of a man, 02:32:06.640 |
Now, Rose Friedman did some very important economic work. 02:32:18.720 |
if she wanted to be married and have children in the world 02:32:30.720 |
like, you know, he's the man out in the world 02:32:33.800 |
It's interesting because her brother, Aaron Director, 02:32:36.560 |
He was very private man, very shy, very introverted. 02:32:39.840 |
And he exerted this like quiet intellectual influence 02:32:44.080 |
So I think that was just kind of a family trait 02:32:47.000 |
of being more quiet, preferring to be behind the scenes. 02:33:04.320 |
When David came along, I lost the other half." 02:33:07.320 |
So it was a household that was just dominated 02:33:10.640 |
by male voices in which she didn't have a lot of room. 02:33:21.280 |
So I really had trouble finding her actual voice 02:33:28.800 |
So it's absolutely essential piece of his success 02:33:34.000 |
to do the Newsweek column, to do Free to Choose. 02:33:43.280 |
And that became this kind of testimony of his ideas, 02:33:50.840 |
When I think of Friedman, if you take away Anna Schwartz, 02:33:54.920 |
if you take away the other woman who collaborated with him, 02:33:57.680 |
you have a much thinner resume than the one he actually has. 02:34:01.160 |
- Yeah, it's always sad and it always makes me wonder 02:34:04.320 |
about the private secret conversations between partners. 02:34:10.400 |
Because they might not show up in the record, 02:34:27.080 |
to another great mind of the 20th century, Ayn Rand. 02:34:32.840 |
We talked about some of the similarities here 02:34:43.640 |
If you can give a big, 10,000-word summary of objectivism. 02:34:54.000 |
So it goes something like epistemology, reason, 02:35:05.760 |
there's a couple of things she did with objectivism. 02:35:08.200 |
First of all, she says the key defining element 02:35:11.680 |
of humanity is rationalism, the rational faculty. 02:35:40.240 |
And that rationality teaches that what you should do 02:35:50.720 |
Now, it's tricky because selfishness has so many strong 02:36:00.880 |
to self-actualization because she really tried 02:36:09.560 |
that to be truly selfish did not mean trampling on others. 02:36:18.120 |
by your own kind of internal measures and metrics. 02:36:23.080 |
And so in her fiction, she tries to show this 02:36:26.920 |
by showing the false selfishness of Peter Keating, 02:36:31.320 |
who's an architect who kind of steps over everybody 02:36:37.320 |
because true selfishness would recognize it's false 02:36:40.880 |
to take others' work and pass it off as your own. 02:36:53.440 |
of revaluing values or a genealogy of morals. 02:37:29.920 |
This is what she's trying to do with objectivism. 02:37:41.400 |
she's flying in the face of the way human morals 02:37:48.200 |
And she's not able to single-handedly recreate them 02:37:52.760 |
- Yeah, I mean, she's not doing herself any favors 02:38:01.640 |
It's like, can we just call it self-actualization? 02:38:05.560 |
- There's a negative connotation to selfishness 02:38:13.600 |
takes on the hardest possible form of argument. 02:38:23.200 |
Nathaniel Brandon, and he was sort of an advisor, 02:38:25.280 |
and he said, "Can you please not use selfishness? 02:38:35.120 |
- I mean, people should listen to her public talks. 02:38:46.680 |
and she's a real powerhouse of an intellectual. 02:38:51.800 |
And that, just listening to her in itself is just inspiring 02:38:56.480 |
'cause you could see the individualism radiate from her. 02:39:01.400 |
- Yeah, I mean, that was one of the things I found 02:39:06.520 |
She's an incredibly unusual human being, you know? 02:39:12.760 |
'cause she's so unusual, but it was also her downfall 02:39:20.840 |
and she never quite processed how different she was 02:39:24.840 |
- So just because we talked about Milton Friedman so much, 02:39:33.600 |
is the interesting differences about Ayn Rand, 02:39:44.120 |
- Yeah, I mean, broadly, we could put Milton Friedman 02:39:46.160 |
and Ayn Rand in some sort of category together, 02:39:48.840 |
but she has this focus on ethics and rationality 02:40:00.960 |
Friedman wanted to overthrow the economic consensus. 02:40:16.220 |
and he says you basically cannot build an ethics 02:40:19.960 |
out of competition because it would be monstrous to do so, 02:40:23.600 |
because it would say the winner of this competition 02:40:28.800 |
and that would open the door to sort of might makes right. 02:40:33.440 |
and he says, "I can't take capitalist outcomes 02:40:40.600 |
And there's this line where Frank Knight says, 02:41:04.080 |
Now, what she's able to do is create a fictional world 02:41:07.360 |
in which people succeed in her fictional capitalist world 02:41:14.520 |
with a capitalist world in which people succeed 02:41:17.480 |
through fraud and corruption and all the other things 02:41:34.760 |
when everybody is emphasizing the downsides of capitalism. 02:41:38.020 |
And she says there's another way to look at it. 02:41:52.200 |
these capitalists, that are like the highest form, 02:41:56.280 |
these great heroic figures, almost romanticizing them. 02:42:02.800 |
as one of the books that you like of hers the most, 02:42:09.600 |
with "The Fountainhead" and "Alice Shrugged"? 02:42:12.820 |
What to you are some sort of memorable, inspiring moments, 02:42:20.200 |
that may be scenes or ideas that you take away from them 02:42:32.160 |
is this story of a struggling architect, Howard Rourke, 02:42:37.160 |
and she kind of follows his life and his career. 02:42:42.920 |
it's a version of to thine own self be true, right? 02:42:54.600 |
and is just focused on his own visions, his own genius. 02:43:12.520 |
who is in some sort of adversarial relationship 02:43:15.660 |
with Howard Rourke and says something to him like, 02:43:33.960 |
and you're not doing it to impress other people, 02:43:39.120 |
You're doing it 'cause you're sort of expressing 02:43:43.520 |
So that has been very captivating to so many, 02:43:55.320 |
- And I think there's also the scene where Rourke, 02:44:05.280 |
So this is the Dean of Architecture that expels Rourke, 02:44:10.880 |
thinking Rourke will plead for a second chance. 02:44:15.060 |
"Rourke's work is contrary to every principle 02:44:24.260 |
"Do you mean to tell me that you're thinking seriously 02:44:26.400 |
"of building that way when and if you are an architect?" 02:44:30.600 |
And then, in a gangster-like way, Rourke says, "Yes." 02:44:34.680 |
And then Dean asks, "My dear fellow, who will let you?" 02:44:45.080 |
I mean, you know, "Ran"'s coming from communist Russia, 02:44:47.320 |
but it has a bit of the "don't mess with Texas" flavor, 02:45:00.680 |
where he says something like, "I inherit no tradition. 02:45:07.220 |
And I really think "Ran"'s thinking about herself, 02:45:10.600 |
that she inherits nothing, she stands at the start. 02:45:16.600 |
and it's not expect, "Ran" is an unknown writer. 02:45:29.440 |
The editor who read it said, "This book is great." 02:45:33.880 |
And he said, "If you don't take this book, I'm quitting." 02:45:37.240 |
You know, and so she idolized him for doing that. 02:45:40.580 |
So they print it, and it becomes a bestseller 02:45:47.780 |
but people tell each other how much they like this book. 02:45:51.320 |
And it keeps printing and selling out printings. 02:45:54.600 |
And so it lands in this time when Americans are engaged 02:45:58.000 |
in this great collective endeavor of World War II. 02:46:00.240 |
They're making all kinds of sacrifices for the collective. 02:46:06.800 |
of someone who doesn't have to compromise at all, 02:46:09.440 |
you know, who is leading their life exactly as they want to. 02:46:14.480 |
on an ocean liner because they've been drafted 02:46:16.260 |
to fight in this war, and they're reading "The Fountainhead" 02:46:21.520 |
"The Fountainhead" is hugely popular in India, 02:46:31.960 |
into a very traditional and conformist culture, 02:46:34.320 |
and people just latch onto it, and they love it." 02:46:38.200 |
of freedom and possibility that they're hoping for. 02:46:45.800 |
but it's more of the philosophy, objectivism, 02:47:02.600 |
- And, you know, Rand knew that she was doing that, 02:47:25.440 |
And she also knew that she was writing, you know, 02:47:28.320 |
people say, "Oh, Rand is for, you know, adolescents. 02:47:34.360 |
And she said, "You know, I'm writing for people 02:47:37.040 |
and they're thinking about who they want to be." 02:47:39.800 |
So she's not writing, you know, for the weary middle age. 02:47:52.840 |
I know a lot of people for whom "The Alchemist," 02:47:55.800 |
and they're adults, and they're brilliant people, 02:48:00.440 |
And the same can be said about "The Fountainhead." 02:48:15.240 |
And the cliche thing sometimes needs to be said. 02:48:27.440 |
because that's the thing that resonates with us. 02:48:30.200 |
- 'Cause we are like heroes of our own story, 02:48:34.840 |
to take the bold step, to take the risk, to take the leap. 02:48:39.680 |
she knew she was doing kind of propaganda in a way. 02:48:42.880 |
She was like, "I'm doing pro-capitalist propaganda." 02:48:45.200 |
She has a degree from the University of Leningrad. 02:49:00.560 |
- I mean, I think it's because of that purity 02:49:03.240 |
that I'm willing to say, sort of, "You get what you deserve." 02:49:17.640 |
And so you don't have contingency or accident or bad luck, 02:49:27.640 |
You know, you just have this idealized world. 02:49:39.760 |
And how can you be missing, what seems to many people, 02:49:50.520 |
And they don't want to see anyone go that far. 02:49:53.520 |
And they're outraged that someone went that far, 02:49:56.240 |
did the thing that Frank Knight said no one would do. 02:50:07.960 |
is just how black and white it paints the world? 02:50:12.640 |
Or if not, what would you say are the flaws of objectivism? 02:50:17.640 |
- So, I mean, the big flaw is that it's justified 02:50:26.080 |
You know, it's not empirical in a way, it's not. 02:50:30.960 |
And Rand herself would say that she's not writing 02:50:33.560 |
about things how they are, but how they should be. 02:50:47.520 |
- And that is a big contrast with Milton Friedman 02:50:54.640 |
- And then I think it's the problem of elevating rationality 02:51:02.760 |
and I describe this in some detail in the book, 02:51:05.360 |
is she essentially creates a cult of reason around her 02:51:14.960 |
It's a group of young people in New York City 02:51:17.440 |
who are drawn to her work and she's already famous, 02:51:21.640 |
and so she's sharing drafts of "Atlas Shrugged" 02:51:28.600 |
to bring all of this together is Alan Greenspan, 02:51:38.520 |
I never thought about ethics or politics or anything bigger 02:51:41.840 |
until I met Ayn Rand and she really opened my mind." 02:51:48.320 |
they think of themselves, we are all individualists. 02:51:50.440 |
We're dedicated to individualism and capitalism. 02:51:54.800 |
Over time, they all come to share Ayn Rand's views 02:51:58.440 |
and opinions on everything from music to art to clothes. 02:52:05.160 |
and a bunch of them get the same dining room table 02:52:10.920 |
because they've all believed they're acting rationally 02:52:23.400 |
And so to disagree with her is to be irrational. 02:52:29.720 |
in this very damaging cult-like circle around her. 02:52:33.800 |
- Plus, for a cult of reason, they get awfully emotional 02:52:45.600 |
but it's also beautiful to watch this singular figure. 02:52:52.160 |
We've talked about several singular figures in "Like Frank," 02:52:54.880 |
right, that shakes up the world with her ideas. 02:53:07.900 |
So Murray Rothbard, who's a famous anarchist, 02:53:10.000 |
falls into the Ayn Rand cult and then he disagrees 02:53:20.200 |
and then he has a little sort of pseudo-cult of his own. 02:53:23.240 |
And two of his cult members switch over to Ayn Rand 02:53:26.840 |
and then one of them, to gesture their breaking 02:53:31.840 |
of their relationship, mails him a dollar bill 02:53:36.920 |
I mean, this is high theatrics, right? (laughs) 02:53:41.000 |
- Okay, sticking on the drama and the theatrics, 02:53:47.500 |
- Take me through the arc of Ayn Rand's relationship 02:53:50.460 |
with Nathaniel Brandon to their dramatic falling out in 1968. 02:54:02.860 |
where she's gonna help in the writing of the film. 02:54:06.660 |
And she's also still working in screenwriting 02:54:09.480 |
And so she gets a letter from a Canadian student 02:54:15.860 |
And then he writes again and he says, "I'm at UCLA." 02:54:18.520 |
And she's like, "Young man, you're so full of error. 02:54:20.500 |
Why don't you come visit me and I'll straighten you out?" 02:54:23.620 |
So he comes and they have this real meeting of the minds, 02:54:27.900 |
He comes again, he brings his girlfriend, she loves him. 02:54:31.020 |
And they start this very intense relationship 02:54:34.180 |
of spending every weekend at her house, basically. 02:54:41.960 |
Rand begins counseling him and his girlfriend 02:54:45.340 |
about their relationship, very intense thing. 02:54:51.260 |
and they both enroll in a graduate program in Columbia. 02:54:55.500 |
And after they've left, Ayn Rand is just bereft. 02:54:59.360 |
And within a few months, she packs up her home 02:55:05.420 |
And so that becomes the seedbed of the collective. 02:55:15.900 |
but many people pointed out it has the word Rand in the name. 02:55:24.580 |
And time goes on and romantic feelings develop 02:55:31.900 |
And they discuss them and they realize that rationality 02:55:36.580 |
has led them to the conclusion that they should be lovers. 02:55:41.980 |
But because they're rational, they need the consent 02:55:49.180 |
So they call a meeting and they obtain the consent 02:55:58.940 |
but this is only going to be an intellectual relationship, 02:56:10.620 |
know and approve, one thing leads to another. 02:56:13.940 |
It becomes a full romantic and sexual relationship. 02:56:17.340 |
And although it's open within these four people, 02:56:21.340 |
And so in all these meetings of the collective, 02:56:24.300 |
Alan Greenspan, all these other people coming up, 02:56:55.160 |
but the close personal relationship continues. 02:57:06.080 |
he has started the Nathaniel Brandon Institute 02:57:15.820 |
And at first it was to help her in her depression. 02:57:18.780 |
She said, "The world needs to recognize your genius. 02:57:37.380 |
objectivists are involved in criticizing the draft. 02:57:42.540 |
there's kind of a libertarian objectivist world going on. 02:58:03.680 |
And finally, Barbara Brandon says to Nathaniel Brandon, 02:58:11.680 |
So she finds out and the whole thing blows up 02:58:14.560 |
and she exiles him and she breaks off contact with him. 02:58:33.600 |
"and I'm not just gonna take her word for it. 02:58:54.060 |
because Rand herself was so controlling over her ideas. 02:58:58.600 |
And now that she steps back from a public role, 02:59:17.760 |
you know, the human potential movement, California. 02:59:20.720 |
And Ayn Rand lives, you know, another 10 years or so, 02:59:32.440 |
although rationalized, some strange sexual partnerships 02:59:41.440 |
and the quote-unquote "rape scene" in the Fountainhead. 02:59:45.320 |
Was she intending to add that there to be controversial? 03:00:04.320 |
- Yeah, I mean, there's also an objectivist theory 03:00:06.720 |
of sexuality that probably the least convincing 03:00:14.160 |
your sexual desires express your highest values 03:00:19.160 |
and they are related in some ways to your rationality, 03:00:23.480 |
right, which is also related to your highest values. 03:00:29.920 |
to Nathaniel Brandon and Nathaniel Brandon's attraction 03:00:32.720 |
to her was a function of their highest values. 03:00:38.040 |
that the fact that he was later drawn sexually 03:00:40.560 |
to a woman who was not particularly accomplished 03:00:43.040 |
but was beautiful, caused him deep anguish and guilt 03:01:11.440 |
and she doesn't consider herself to have a beautiful face. 03:01:20.720 |
She finds love with a man who is very handsome 03:01:23.680 |
but very passive, yet she writes in all her fiction 03:01:32.520 |
The man she's actually with is not a strong manly hero. 03:01:37.080 |
she probably wouldn't be able to be in the same room 03:01:42.760 |
And then she develops this theory about women and men 03:01:56.800 |
So again, this is not at all how Ayn Rand lives her life. 03:01:59.720 |
This is like this, I would say, compensatory theory 03:02:13.360 |
and almost distorted and exaggerated way to compensate 03:02:16.880 |
for the fact that she doesn't actually meet them, 03:02:21.040 |
The rape scene to some degree embodies that idea 03:02:24.920 |
that to some degree that the woman should worship the man. 03:02:29.920 |
I tend to read it more in terms of literary genre. 03:02:33.600 |
So Rand is a screenwriter, a consumer of movies, 03:02:46.440 |
In other words, these like pulpy romance novels 03:02:57.600 |
but if you were reading a bunch of novels in this genre, 03:03:03.760 |
And so, but that is a huge part of his appeal at the time. 03:03:07.240 |
There's this feminist who hates Rand, Susan Brownmiller, 03:03:14.440 |
So she goes to get the fountainhead and she's wondering 03:03:16.680 |
how is she ever gonna find the scene in this 800-page book. 03:03:20.640 |
It's a library copy 'cause she doesn't wanna buy it. 03:03:27.080 |
because it's very racy and explicit for that time. 03:03:33.520 |
Like if I put in this kind of taboo-breaking sex scene, 03:03:42.280 |
I think all of the gender and sexuality stuff 03:03:49.920 |
- I think it also reminds me of another guy related, 03:03:53.680 |
Friedrich Nietzsche, who had very strong opinions on women 03:03:58.120 |
and wrote about what women's role in society should be 03:04:02.600 |
and different power dynamics and relationships 03:04:09.920 |
- And so you have to sort of always maybe chuckle 03:04:17.600 |
of power dynamics and relationship from these figures 03:04:19.840 |
which failed in many regards in their own private life. 03:04:32.560 |
because she then goes on and someone writes her a letter 03:04:38.920 |
about like, should there be a female president or something? 03:04:44.760 |
And she says, "No, no woman should ever be president 03:04:58.400 |
"and like rotten in the soul and like unfit to be a leader." 03:05:06.120 |
and she's one of the most powerful intellects 03:05:12.200 |
I mean, Nietzsche is full of contradictions of this sort. 03:05:15.620 |
That the very fact that she's one of the most powerful minds 03:05:20.620 |
in history to me means that she is a feminist 03:05:31.320 |
- I mean, she lived the ideals of individualism in her life 03:05:48.480 |
So if feminism has some sort of collective aspect to it 03:05:57.520 |
one needs to identify with a broader category of woman 03:06:11.520 |
but did not, I mean, she was very negative about feminism. 03:06:14.960 |
And then because like they dress terribly, you know? 03:06:18.080 |
And then the other thing, it's really interesting. 03:06:20.160 |
She had, there's all these kinds of homoerotic themes 03:06:24.280 |
And for that reason, many gay men were drawn to her writing. 03:06:32.080 |
You know, she would denounce people for being homosexual. 03:06:34.800 |
So there's a whole actual literature of like gay men 03:06:50.080 |
I just think of the enormous pressure she was under 03:06:56.200 |
and her just utter inability to meet any of them. 03:06:59.040 |
And it came out in this very tortured set of ideals 03:07:04.840 |
And this kind of lack of ability to introspect in herself 03:07:09.480 |
and to, it was probably too painful to introspect 03:07:13.920 |
So she just tried to rationalize her way through it. 03:07:18.360 |
And it came out in these very strange theories. 03:07:24.280 |
maybe you can correct me, but as far as I can see, 03:07:27.200 |
never mentioned in the list of great thinkers in history 03:07:29.840 |
or even the great thinkers of the 20th century, 03:07:32.280 |
or even the great female thinkers of the 20th century. 03:07:36.080 |
So you have somebody like Simone de Beauvoir, Hannah Arend. 03:07:42.920 |
If you Google those silly lists, top, whatever, 03:07:47.920 |
top thinkers of the 20th century, she's not mentioned. 03:07:52.040 |
- You know, a lot of people just deeply dislike Rand. 03:07:58.640 |
because they're disconnection from other ideas 03:08:04.560 |
I think where you could look at them and say, 03:08:07.800 |
these ideas are very provocative and they're very deep 03:08:21.600 |
Like, how could you even make these contentions? 03:08:25.320 |
And I think that because she's not without precedence 03:08:31.040 |
but she doesn't knit herself into an intellectual community 03:08:35.120 |
the way that these other thinkers do very naturally, 03:08:45.040 |
You know, I think my book was one of the first 03:08:56.360 |
You know, I think now people are more open to it. 03:09:00.160 |
But I think the people who compile these lists 03:09:10.760 |
They find her work in the mythic register simple. 03:09:25.160 |
You know, he's not a thinker of the mid 20th century. 03:09:40.040 |
rather than being rooted in a theory of human nature 03:09:51.200 |
in the United States over the past 100 years, 03:09:59.320 |
over the populace, over our government, over culture? 03:10:19.280 |
- Yeah, I mean, there's a couple of different ways 03:10:36.360 |
that make that idea resonate or not resonate. 03:10:46.040 |
I'm studying ideas and I'm always putting them 03:10:49.280 |
Like what is happening that is making these things resonate, 03:11:01.200 |
which is one of these defining moments of the time. 03:11:04.800 |
And then I think the idea comes out in a sort of pure form 03:11:11.920 |
And I'm really interested in how people form communities 03:11:15.360 |
So a bunch of people started calling themselves objectivists 03:11:33.440 |
that's been institutionalized in universities. 03:11:42.720 |
but really emblematic ways of how ideas spread. 03:11:56.120 |
well, maybe I don't like Franklin Roosevelt so much, 03:11:58.160 |
or maybe I'll look another time at Barry Goldwater. 03:12:01.800 |
And then whereas Friedman, you get the idea more top down, 03:12:08.120 |
within a sort of elite discourse of economics. 03:12:11.200 |
And so I think they kind of go top down and bottom up 03:12:21.400 |
that really made people think they proved out. 03:12:26.560 |
in Cold War America that's looking for a statement of like, 03:12:31.680 |
What does it mean to live in this mass society? 03:12:34.240 |
Because it's also a time of great social conformity 03:12:44.000 |
The United States is stepping out onto the world stage. 03:12:48.360 |
What does it mean to be an individual in that world? 03:12:54.560 |
about how they trickle through different levels of society 03:13:07.640 |
and how that evolves into the Bolshevik Revolution 03:13:11.760 |
and how that like takes hold in its implementations. 03:13:14.520 |
Or you can think about Nazism and with Hitler 03:13:25.680 |
and takes hold in power and then that has its consequences. 03:13:30.520 |
- When I think about this sort of historical path 03:13:39.480 |
I mean, in many ways it has some echoes with Ran 03:13:47.480 |
is almost, it's a rationalist ideology of some ways. 03:13:55.000 |
I think she is one of the most kind of penetrating analyses 03:13:57.960 |
of communism, which she really puts in the category 03:14:07.360 |
and then experience crops up and experience is different. 03:14:15.720 |
Well, it tries to bend experience to its will. 03:14:22.520 |
So the question though is why does it catch fire? 03:14:28.560 |
Why does it draw people into political allegiance? 03:14:36.680 |
dream of equality, dream of the powerless rising up 03:14:44.120 |
And then you had the whole addition of Leninism, 03:14:48.120 |
which gave a kind of international cast to that 03:14:50.680 |
and helped people think about what are the relations 03:14:55.320 |
and what can we expect out of them and what might happen, 03:14:57.480 |
gave a sort of a framework for thinking about that 03:15:00.320 |
in a time when the world was becoming more interconnected 03:15:04.080 |
and those differences were becoming more obvious. 03:15:06.520 |
Fascism to me is unleashing more something primal, 03:15:12.640 |
something sort of dark and primal within people. 03:15:16.800 |
And it's more a permission structure to indulge in that 03:15:23.120 |
Those impulses are normally channeled or held down. 03:15:25.520 |
And it seems that when the fascist regimes come into power, 03:15:28.680 |
they give people permission to let those forces out. 03:15:33.800 |
going back to that lecture that Ayn Rand gave, 03:15:47.720 |
towards the people that have nots versus the haves. 03:15:53.880 |
And there is some degree to which Nazism has the same 03:16:12.840 |
and just constructing a narrative around that, 03:16:19.240 |
- Yeah, it seems like communism is more animated 03:16:26.520 |
And fascism seems like the process of scapegoating, right? 03:16:40.560 |
- There is a primal thing going back to literature in 1984, 03:16:55.000 |
where you, once you're in that state of hate, 03:16:58.040 |
anyone can direct that hate towards anything. 03:17:28.960 |
almost the opposite of Ayn Rand's philosophy. 03:17:40.600 |
- Yeah, I mean, I think in the broadest sense, 03:17:52.680 |
an elite space, out to more popular dimensions? 03:18:20.160 |
People take economics as a theory of the world 03:18:29.400 |
And in both cases, how do those ideas travel? 03:18:35.160 |
if you read the original "Postmodern Thinkers," 03:18:40.280 |
I mean, I make my students do it and they suffer. 03:18:58.440 |
that say from Milton Friedman's economic theory 03:19:28.600 |
like distilled down and then turning into its opposite. 03:19:39.880 |
you know, postmodernism started about disrupting binaries. 03:19:50.840 |
to the reinscribing of many different binaries. 03:19:56.120 |
has become this like paradigmatic set of glasses 03:20:00.400 |
So I think the dynamics are very, very similar. 03:20:02.760 |
So I think it's something in the traffic of the idea 03:20:22.240 |
- By the way, that going from pure form to popular form, 03:20:25.660 |
I remember, this might be before the internet, 03:20:28.440 |
but when I was in college reading Derrida and Foucault, 03:20:38.200 |
like I'm able to read pure encapsulations of an idea 03:20:48.080 |
if you actually take the pure form of that idea 03:20:57.060 |
That's not, although I do consider myself sexually 03:21:13.400 |
let's say the biographies of Milton Friedman and Ayn Rand 03:21:42.920 |
I feel like I'm communing with the dead in some ways. 03:21:53.240 |
it's gotta be something that gets you out of bed 03:21:59.680 |
there's nowhere to go, there's nowhere to be. 03:22:02.660 |
'cause you're interested in what you wanna study. 03:22:04.280 |
And so with Rand, it was this real sense of discovery. 03:22:06.560 |
Like I am discovering, I wanna know about this woman, 03:22:10.720 |
And the only way to find out is to do the research. 03:22:25.240 |
I don't know that I would do it independently. 03:22:27.240 |
So the first was a graduate program in history, 03:22:30.920 |
And so I had coursework and then I had structures 03:22:34.800 |
and I did have people to check in with and read, 03:23:03.880 |
who took it upon himself to throw at me everything 03:23:06.800 |
he thought the outside world would throw at me. 03:23:20.320 |
because I knew it was an unconventional choice 03:23:27.120 |
I just said, well, I'm gonna do this and see. 03:23:34.660 |
I started it during second Bush administration, 03:23:42.460 |
People were interested in just conservatism in general 03:23:47.520 |
on the political spectrum felt like objectively, 03:23:49.400 |
we don't know enough about this and this is a problem. 03:23:53.320 |
So I really kind of caught that wave in scholarship 03:24:04.480 |
as you've mentioned, a kind of gateway to conservatism. 03:24:09.240 |
in that people start with Rand, they're taken by her. 03:24:13.440 |
In some ways she takes the worldview of Milton Friedman 03:24:17.400 |
in terms of what capitalism can accomplish economically. 03:24:21.680 |
And then she puts it in this mythopoetic register 03:24:25.660 |
So once people have absorbed that, they want more. 03:24:29.760 |
They go on to learning more of the ideas behind that vision 03:24:33.400 |
or they have become true believers, they've converted. 03:24:36.160 |
And so then they head off to work for a politician, 03:24:38.920 |
to work for a think tank, to work for a party. 03:24:52.760 |
So those were the people I wanted to track very deliberately. 03:24:55.180 |
I wasn't trying to do in the round everything about Ayn Rand. 03:25:01.240 |
goddess of the market, Ayn Rand and the American right 03:25:06.560 |
those who took her in this political direction? 03:25:10.200 |
- If we return to like the actual, your process. 03:25:14.760 |
- So you're showing up and you're reading sources 03:25:17.680 |
and you're like, is it kind of like the process of discovery? 03:25:28.600 |
or maybe special moments that illustrate an idea emerge. 03:25:32.740 |
- Yeah, I mean, I know with the biography of a person, 03:25:43.900 |
And then with Rand, both with Rand and Friedman, 03:25:50.780 |
'cause I wanted my own experience of the material 03:25:57.620 |
Similarly, I had read some Friedman, but not a lot. 03:25:59.840 |
So I had first is like, let me read the major stuff, 03:26:02.000 |
get oriented and then just dive into the archive 03:26:10.360 |
In Rand's case, I was interested in her in the United States, 03:26:15.800 |
I didn't have the language skills to do that. 03:26:20.040 |
and I start when she publishes her first book 03:26:31.760 |
And once I have enough, I say, well, that's a chapter. 03:26:36.760 |
And then there's gonna be, the book has come out. 03:26:39.980 |
And so now I need to start a different chapter. 03:26:41.600 |
What's her life like after the book has been published? 03:26:46.760 |
although I have this very high level structure, 03:26:48.780 |
it's coming out of the archive, the material I'm finding. 03:27:01.940 |
- And you're trying to understand the relationships. 03:27:03.820 |
It's so fascinating, like reconstruct in a dark room, 03:27:08.100 |
trying to reconstruct, shine a light on relationships 03:27:14.740 |
I mean, correspondence is really, really helpful. 03:27:17.080 |
Drafts, correspondence, and someone this famous, 03:27:20.880 |
they have oral histories, other people write about them. 03:27:30.540 |
in a compelling story and what do I need to explain? 03:27:33.900 |
And then also for me, what was really helpful 03:27:39.360 |
the kind of broad sweep of 20th century history. 03:27:41.740 |
So I know that Rand's involved in a labor action 03:27:53.040 |
And so then that really changes the origin story 03:27:56.360 |
of Atlas Shrubbed, because she's looking at labor actions. 03:28:12.320 |
So then I can kind of take that and run with that 03:28:24.960 |
So what's your, how do you think of teaching? 03:28:35.800 |
The ways the old school kind of dominating way 03:28:44.560 |
and also the students wouldn't respond to it. 03:28:50.520 |
I think that's like almost the number one thing I bring 03:28:53.720 |
Like, look how neat and interesting these ideas are. 03:28:59.440 |
I try to give the fairest possible rendition I can 03:29:08.040 |
and say this kind of, you know, I find this unsettling 03:29:10.600 |
and this, you know, tells me something about myself. 03:29:16.080 |
into the, like the biography of a great thinker, 03:29:24.440 |
And I'll ask the students, what are you finding here? 03:29:32.160 |
and really teaching them how to do deep reading. 03:29:34.540 |
So I feel like that is my contribution right now. 03:29:39.780 |
We're having trouble paying attention collectively 03:29:42.040 |
and I'm trying to cultivate their skills to doing that 03:29:47.560 |
And also modeling, like this is how I would read a text. 03:29:49.820 |
This is what jumps out to me when I look at, you know, 03:29:55.080 |
And just show them that studying a history of ideas 03:29:59.080 |
I feel incredibly privileged to do it, you know? 03:30:02.760 |
I think this is the time for students in college, 03:30:10.200 |
They can really handle complicated, hard ideas. 03:30:13.160 |
They don't always have the context behind them. 03:30:14.920 |
So I need to give them the hard ideas and then show them, 03:30:16.960 |
this is kind of the context of what's happening in the world. 03:30:19.960 |
But really, I'm just, I'm showing them the landscape. 03:30:25.720 |
We have a 10 week quarter, you know, giving them a flyover. 03:30:43.800 |
in terms of reading about ideas you agree with 03:30:48.520 |
- I mean, even though I think the passion is important 03:31:07.300 |
Like, I'm like, oh, there you go again, you know, 03:31:09.680 |
or like, well, that's gonna cause trouble, lady. 03:31:19.740 |
I'm not expecting to have the light shine on me. 03:31:30.640 |
but, and then I just try to find the humor in it. 03:31:52.340 |
Like, that's how weird of a guy he was, you know? 03:31:56.660 |
keep alert for those funny kind of human touches 03:31:59.180 |
that like, these are ultimately just people, you know, 03:32:01.740 |
people with ideas that they spent enough time polishing up 03:32:04.300 |
and developing that we still want to read about them 03:32:10.620 |
Do you think there's some ideas that are good 03:32:15.780 |
or is it more complicated like the old Solzhenitsyn line 03:32:23.340 |
- I mean, I philosophically agree with Solzhenitsyn for sure. 03:32:29.420 |
and some ideas pull on the bad side, like absolutely. 03:32:34.820 |
that's probably why people dislike Rand so much 03:32:37.140 |
is they feel like she's giving license to the bad side 03:32:40.340 |
and she's saying it's okay to be selfish and it's okay. 03:32:42.820 |
You know, they feel like she's unloosing the dark forces. 03:32:45.720 |
And, you know, in some cases that may be true, 03:32:50.740 |
but I also, she's also unloosing some of the light forces 03:32:54.240 |
in terms of reflecting on yourself and trying to be true. 03:32:57.580 |
But definitely there are ideas that are dangerous 03:33:00.740 |
to play with and their ideas that I think give license 03:33:06.160 |
But I think you can see that in the historical record. 03:33:17.980 |
like Germany, they think the ideas are so dangerous 03:33:22.540 |
And in some contexts that may absolutely be true. 03:33:28.500 |
with a grain of salt because perhaps censorship 03:33:33.020 |
So all of that, that's the beautiful thing about us humans. 03:33:36.540 |
We are always at attention trying to figure out 03:33:45.100 |
Pothead question, do humans have ideas or do ideas have us? 03:33:53.660 |
after Rutgers trying to figure out what he can do 03:34:06.700 |
They're just kind of like travel through human brains 03:34:10.460 |
and like captivate us and we get all real excited. 03:34:15.460 |
Like with the monolith in 2001 Space Odyssey, 03:34:34.460 |
in an implementation of some action that results 03:34:37.420 |
in us figuring out that that idea was actually bad 03:34:41.700 |
But it feels like the idea is riding the show. 03:34:47.780 |
You know, there, Keynes has this famous quote like, 03:34:50.020 |
you know, most men are slaves of some defunct economist. 03:34:52.940 |
You know, and so-- - That's funny, that's funny. 03:34:56.540 |
- So I do think that we, like it's really hard 03:35:02.620 |
we encounter the same situations again and again. 03:35:05.740 |
And so it's really hard, you're born into these traditions 03:35:11.340 |
and most people are never gonna question them 03:35:13.500 |
and most people are never gonna become aware of them. 03:35:15.700 |
So again, that's some of the work of what I do 03:35:18.020 |
as an intellectual historian is like, let's become aware. 03:35:23.100 |
that's orienting you to the world in a certain way, right? 03:35:26.500 |
And so I think you have to work really, really hard 03:35:31.580 |
And even then, it's not a completely original idea. 03:35:34.820 |
It's a reworking and a reassembling of ideas others have had. 03:35:50.620 |
And that's fine, they wanna have experiences, 03:35:52.580 |
they wanna do other things with their life, you know. 03:35:58.780 |
and thank you so much for your incredible work. 03:36:01.500 |
It was really fun and fascinating to talk with you today. 03:36:07.180 |
- Thank you for listening to this conversation 03:36:13.620 |
and articulate some things I've been thinking about. 03:36:22.180 |
at the end of episodes, go to lexfriedman.com/ama 03:36:33.100 |
Please allow me to say a few words about my interview 03:36:35.980 |
with the president of Ukraine, Volodymyr Zelensky. 03:36:45.940 |
future upcoming conversations, and what it all means 03:36:49.420 |
for the war in Ukraine, for global geopolitics, 03:36:55.500 |
I've gotten a lot of heartfelt, positive words 03:37:01.380 |
literally everybody who knows me personally inside Ukraine, 03:37:30.260 |
There was none of that here, at least so far. 03:37:37.700 |
The most common message was please keep pushing for peace. 03:37:43.980 |
But online, on the interwebs, I saw a lot of attacks, 03:37:58.540 |
who, by the way, thinks the attacks are all propped up 03:38:09.540 |
Just keep focused on the mission of pushing for peace. 03:38:17.860 |
who, to this day, says don't read the comments. 03:38:20.900 |
This is generally good advice, and I try to follow it, 03:38:27.420 |
and this interview, this war, for me, is deeply personal. 03:38:35.620 |
and lies about the conversation and about me personally 03:38:49.100 |
with President Zelensky and conversations in general. 03:38:52.980 |
This interview is something I poured my heart and soul into, 03:38:58.860 |
I've described parts of the preparation process I follow 03:39:04.220 |
but in general, let me say that I've read a lot, 03:39:07.500 |
listened to a lot, and had a lot of private conversations 03:39:18.020 |
Two low-effort attacks got to me a bit, if I'm being honest, 03:39:22.900 |
though I am learning to take it all in stride. 03:39:25.900 |
First attack is that I'm unprepared, uninformed, or naive. 03:39:41.860 |
It never will be the case for future conversations, 03:39:50.820 |
Second low-effort attack that got to me a bit 03:39:55.580 |
is that I'm a shill for Zelensky or a shill for Putin. 03:39:59.580 |
Both accusations were hurled readily and freely 03:40:05.460 |
by the left and the right in the United States and Europe, 03:40:09.140 |
by the pro and the anti-Zelensky people in Ukraine 03:40:14.060 |
and by the pro and anti-Putin people in Russia 03:40:19.500 |
As I've said over and over, this is not the case 03:40:28.660 |
More than that, I just simply refuse to be caught 03:40:37.340 |
and the various dogmatic groups and tribes out there 03:40:40.540 |
want to pull you in to their warm embrace of belonging 03:40:50.740 |
is that I will never belong to any one group. 03:40:54.180 |
In the end, like many of us must, I walk alone. 03:41:11.340 |
First, give a large platform to President Zelensky 03:41:16.940 |
and to do so in a way that brings out the best 03:41:30.780 |
and to provide his vision for what that might look like. 03:41:33.780 |
And just to be clear, by peace, I mean long lasting peace 03:41:38.620 |
that minimizes suffering of people in the region 03:41:46.020 |
The war in Ukraine has led to over 1 million casualties 03:41:57.260 |
tormented and forced into a state of anger and hate, 03:42:02.960 |
To them, nothing less than justice must be accepted. 03:42:14.540 |
It's true, peace will not bring back your loved ones, 03:42:20.100 |
but it will prevent further slaughter of more people, 03:42:26.020 |
So again, the second goal of this conversation 03:42:40.000 |
so let me try to explain my approach for this one. 03:42:42.500 |
As I've said, I read and listened to a lot of material 03:42:49.540 |
There would be many weeks over the past three years 03:42:51.580 |
where I would spend every day, over eight hours a day, 03:43:00.400 |
that I consistently returned to and researched, 03:43:05.200 |
was always peace talks, not just in this war, 03:43:11.020 |
For this specific war, as part of the background prep, 03:43:15.660 |
I would take notes on every single perspective I could find 03:43:18.760 |
on every single major diplomatic meeting and negotiation 03:43:22.020 |
that happened in Ukraine-Russia relations since 1991. 03:43:36.060 |
that President Zelensky spoke about in this podcast. 03:43:41.600 |
Andrei Bohdan was interviewed twice by Dmitry Gordon 03:43:52.820 |
The two interviews are 7 1/2 hours, by the way, 03:44:01.600 |
Andrei Bohdan worked directly with President Zelensky 03:44:06.000 |
as the head of the Office of the President of Ukraine. 03:44:09.020 |
He was there for the 2019 face-to-face meeting 03:44:22.300 |
This was part of the Normandy format peace talks. 03:44:28.120 |
Andrei Bohdan gave a very different perspective 03:44:31.320 |
on that 2019 meeting than did President Zelensky 03:44:47.760 |
to dive into that data point and be critical. 03:44:54.880 |
I am interested, once again, in productive conversations, 03:44:58.840 |
critical or otherwise, that push towards peace, 03:45:11.660 |
But all of it taken together made it clear to me, 03:45:17.360 |
that it is indeed very difficult but possible 03:45:21.540 |
to negotiate long-lasting peace with Vladimir Putin. 03:45:25.200 |
It is certainly true that Ukraine is best positioned 03:45:50.340 |
with a successful counter-offensive in Kherson and Kharkiv. 03:45:59.660 |
Donald Trump is very interested in making peace. 03:46:02.780 |
It is likely that the U.S. financial support for this war 03:46:08.040 |
So the leverage and the timing for peace negotiation is now. 03:46:12.080 |
There is unlikely to be another chance like this 03:46:18.460 |
Just to zoom out on the conversation piece of this, 03:46:22.000 |
I interviewed Donald Trump and may do so again. 03:46:25.620 |
I interviewed Vladimir Zelensky and may do so again. 03:46:28.740 |
And it seems likely that I will interview Vladimir Putin 03:46:42.180 |
I merely want to do my small part in pushing for peace. 03:46:45.180 |
In a moment in history, when there's a real chance 03:46:55.100 |
But I can probably speak for many more hours. 03:46:59.500 |
So again, my two goals were to bring out the best 03:47:03.420 |
in President Zelensky as a leader and a human being, 03:47:16.020 |
Like I said, step one through 10 is prepare well. 03:47:19.900 |
I did, but step 11 is the actual conversation. 03:47:24.740 |
There the specific psychological and personality quirks 03:47:30.060 |
My job is to try to cut through the bullshit walls 03:47:32.140 |
we put up as human beings and reveal directly 03:47:35.260 |
or indirectly who the person truly is and how they think. 03:47:43.540 |
and emotional human being who personally feels 03:47:46.860 |
the suffering of the people of Ukraine in this war. 03:47:49.740 |
This is a strength and perhaps also a weakness. 03:47:54.300 |
But it is an important part of the reason why I said 03:47:57.220 |
many times that he is a truly historic figure. 03:48:00.940 |
Very few leaders in recent history would be able 03:48:09.940 |
to join the war effort to the degree they did. 03:48:25.580 |
Sometimes fully self-aware and sometimes losing himself 03:48:29.500 |
in the emotional rollercoaster of a painful memory 03:48:32.380 |
or a turn of phrase that he can use as a springboard 03:48:38.780 |
Add to this, the fact that we didn't agree to anything. 03:48:42.980 |
What we will talk about or how long we will talk about it. 03:48:47.300 |
The interview could have easily been five minutes 03:48:51.020 |
So I had to quickly gain his trust enough to open up 03:48:57.220 |
But push him enough to reveal the complexities 03:49:03.700 |
This is where humor and camaraderie was essential 03:49:08.280 |
Though it was very difficult given the stakes, 03:49:10.900 |
the heaviness, the seriousness of the topic of the war. 03:49:21.180 |
Often using almost childlike statements or questions. 03:49:27.900 |
On the surface, they may seem naive, but they're not. 03:49:40.380 |
that the emperor was not wearing any clothes. 03:49:49.000 |
And that truth is that hundreds of thousands of people 03:49:59.060 |
from corruption to suspended elections to censorship 03:50:31.700 |
that were intensely critical of Vladimir Putin, 03:50:51.260 |
Peacemaking in this situation requires compromise 03:50:56.100 |
in order to avoid further death and suffering. 03:50:59.540 |
And I believe it requires treating the other leader 03:51:02.300 |
with the seriousness you expect him to treat you with. 03:51:13.340 |
which is necessary to accomplish both goals one and two 03:51:40.540 |
As an example, President Zelensky said in a mocking tone 03:51:45.540 |
is simply irritated by people who are alive in Ukraine. 03:51:56.620 |
"If you think that the president of a country 03:51:59.660 |
"it is really hard to come to an agreement with him. 03:52:10.580 |
"And he conducts, yes, destructive military actions." 03:52:14.300 |
The president interrupted me at this point and said, 03:52:47.380 |
discussing the opportunity to negotiate peace 03:52:51.220 |
when a large number of people are dying every single day. 03:53:06.440 |
There are a few other places in the conversation 03:53:09.340 |
where some online mobs took my words out of context 03:53:19.180 |
who they claim is the second coming of Hitler. 03:53:21.520 |
My friends, if you make such attacks on this conversation, 03:53:30.420 |
and ignorant of the facts of history and geopolitics. 03:53:41.100 |
in order for Ukraine to have a chance to flourish, 03:53:44.020 |
and in order for the drums of a global war to stop beating. 03:53:51.780 |
This was my goal, once again, to push for peace, 03:53:57.600 |
and I will continue this effort to the best of my ability.